Pledgeability, Industry Liquidity, and Financing Cycles

AuthorYUNZHI HU,DOUGLAS W. DIAMOND,RAGHURAM G. RAJAN
Published date01 February 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12831
Date01 February 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2020
Pledgeability, Industry Liquidity,
and Financing Cycles
DOUGLAS W. DIAMOND, YUNZHI HU, and RAGHURAM G. RAJAN
ABSTRACT
Why do firms choose high debt when they anticipate high valuations, and underper-
form subsequently? We propose a theory of financing cycles where the importance of
creditors’ control rights over cash flows (“pledgeability”) varies with industry liquidity.
The market allows firms take on more debt when they anticipate higher future liquid-
ity. However, both high anticipated liquidity and the resulting high debt limit their
incentives to enhance pledgeability.This has prolonged adverse effects in a downturn.
Because these effects are hard to contract upon, higher anticipated liquidity can also
reduce a firm’s current access to finance.
WHY DO DOWNTURNS FOLLOWING EPISODES OF HIGH firm valuations result in
more protracted recessions (see Krishnamurthy and Muir (2017), L´
opez-Salido,
Stein, and Zakrajˇ
sek (2017))?1One traditional rationale is based on the idea
of “debt overhang”—debt built up during the boom restricts investment and
borrowing during the bust. However, if everyone knows that debt reduces in-
vestment, debt holders have an incentive to write down the debt in return for a
stake in the firm’s growth. For debt overhang to be a serious concern, the firm
and debt holders must be unable to negotiate value-enhancing contracts. An-
other view is that borrowers cannot be trusted to pursue only value-enhancing
investments, even in a downturn, in which case debt overhang is needed to
constrain the borrower’s investment—overhang is a second-best solution to a
Diamond and Rajan are with Chicago Booth and NBER. Hu is with the University of North
Carolina. Diamond and Rajan thank the Center for Research in Security Prices at Chicago Booth
and the National Science Foundation for research support. Rajan also thanks the Stigler Center.
We are grateful for helpful comments from three referees; the Editor; Florian Heider; Alan Morri-
son; Martin Oehmke; Adriano A. Rampini; workshop participants at the OXFIT 2014 conference,
Chicago Booth, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
the NBER 2015 Corporate Finance Summer Institute, Sciences Po, American Finance Association
meetings in 2016, and Princeton, MIT Sloan, the European Central Bank, Boston University,Har-
vard University, Stanford University, Washington University in St. Louis, and the University of
Maryland. The authors have read the Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts
of interest to disclose.
1Krishnamurthy and Muir (2017) document a negative correlation between precrisis spreads
and credit growth, as well as a positive correlation between the change in spread as the crisis
hits and the severity of the subsequent crisis. L´
opez-Salido, Stein, and Zakrajˇ
sek (2017) show that
narrow credit spreads predict a slowdown in real activity in subsequent years, including in GDP
growth, investment, consumption, and employment.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12831
C2019 the American Finance Association
419
420 The Journal of Finance R
fundamental moral hazard problem (see Hart and Moore (1995) or Shleifer and
Vishny (1992)). The immediate questions raised by the latter view is why would
we want to constrain borrowers more in bad times following high valuations,
when the constraints imposed by debt are already high, and why would the
moral hazard problem be so much more serious in such episodes.
In this paper, we provide an explanation for high debt and show why its
consequences are more acute following periods of high valuations and rational
optimism about future values. In doing so, we differentiate between financier
control rights that are due solely to high resale prices for assets and control
rights that derive from pledging cash flows. The former are especially useful
in enforcing claims during an asset price boom, whereas the latter facilitate
enforcement of external claims at other times, including downturns. The tran-
sition between regimes in which the importance of control rights associated
with cash flows differ significantly causes the debt built up during a boom to
have prolonged adverse effects during a downturn.
To be more specific, consider an industry that requires special industry
knowledge to produce. Within the industry, there are firms run by incumbents,
there are experts (those who know the industry well enough to be able to run
firms as efficiently as the incumbents), and there are industry outsiders (such
as financiers who do not know how to run industry firms but have general
managerial/financial skills).
Financiers have two sorts of control rights: control through the right to re-
possess and sell the underlying asset being financed if payments are missed,
and control over the cash flows generated by the asset. The first right only
requires the frictionless enforcement of property rights in the economy, which
we assume. This right is particularly valuable when a large number of capable
potential buyers are willing to pay a high price for the firm’s assets. Greater
wealth among experts (which we term industry liquidity) increases the avail-
ability of this asset-sale-based financing. Because we analyze a single industry,
high levels of this industry liquidity can be interpreted as an economy-wide
boom.
The second type of control right is conferred on creditors by the firm’s in-
cumbent manager as she makes the firm’s cash flows more appropriable by, or
pledgeable to, creditors over the medium term. For example, she could improve
accounting quality or set up escrow accounts so that cash flows are hard to
divert. In general, an increase in experts’ higher prospective wealth (that is,
liquidity) as well as in their ability to borrow against the future cash flows of
the firm they buy (that is, pledgeability) will increase their bids for the firm.
In turn, higher prospective bids will increase debt recovery, and thus the will-
ingness of creditors to lend up front. It therefore follows that higher liquidity
and pledgeability increase the firm’s debt capacity.
However, pledgeability is endogenously determined. Consider the incentives
of an incumbent firm manager while choosing cash flow pledgeability for the
next period. We assume that she may sell some or all of the firm next period
with some probability, either because she is no longer capable of running it
or because she needs to raise capital for new investment. If she owned the
Pledgeability, Industry Liquidity, and Financing Cycles 421
firm and had no debt claims outstanding, she would undoubtedly want to in-
crease pledgeability, especially if the direct costs of doing so are small—this
would simply increase the amount that she would obtain by selling the firm to
experts if she lost ability to run the firm. If she has taken on debt, however,
enhancing cash flow pledgeability is a double-edged sword. Higher bids from
experts also allow existing creditors to collect more if the incumbent stays in
control because creditors have the right to seize assets and sell them when not
paid in full. In such situations, the incumbent has to “buy” the firm from cred-
itors by outbidding experts (or paying debt fully). The higher the probability
that she retains ability and stays in control, and the higher the outstanding
debt, the lower her incentives to raise pledgeability. Higher outstanding debt
thus reduces the incumbent manager’s incentives to raise pledgeability.
Now consider the effect of industry liquidity on pledgeability choice. If experts
are rational, they will never pay more for the firm than its fundamental value.
When future industry liquidity is very high, experts will have enough wealth
to buy the firm at full value without needing to borrow more against the firm’s
future cash flows. If so, higher pledgeability has no effect on how much experts
will bid to pay for the firm. In other words, high future liquidity crowds out the
need for pledgeability in enhancing debt repayments. We therefore have two
influences on pledgeability—the level of outstanding debt and the anticipated
liquidity of experts. The key results of the paper stem from the interaction
between the two.
To see this, consider a prospective boom, which is anticipated with high
probability, during which experts will have plenty of wealth. Repayment of any
corporate borrowing today is enforced by the potential high resale value of the
firm—at the future date, wealthy experts will bid full value for the firm as in
Shleifer and Vishny (1992), without needing high pledgeability to make their
bid. The high anticipated resale value increases the promised payment that a
firm can credibly repay and thus the amount it can borrow today (see Acharya
and Viswanathan (2011)).
Because pledgeability is not needed to enforce repayment in a future highly
liquid state, a high probability of such a state encourages creditors to lend
large amounts to the incumbent up front, even though they know that doing
so crowds out the incumbent’s incentives to enhance pledgeability, and even
if there is a possible low liquidity state in which pledgeability is needed to
enhance creditor rights. Prospective liquidity thus encourages borrowing, which
can crowd out pledgeability. Consequently, if the low-liquidity state is realized,
the enforceability of the firm’s debt, as well as its borrowing capacity, will fall
significantly because pledgeability has been set low. Experts, also hit by the
downturn, no longer have much personal wealth, nor does the low-cash-flow
pledgeability of the firm allow them to borrow against future cash flows to pay
for the firm. The adverse effect of anticipated liquidity on pledgeability via
higher leverage is a key new focus of this paper.
Because external claims are high in these low-liquidity episodes, the firm may
be sold to outsiders. Although industry outsiders have little ability to operate
the firm themselves, this may be a virtue—outsiders have strong incentives

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT