Persistent and snap decision‐making

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12395
Published date01 February 2021
AuthorTomoya Tajika
Date01 February 2021
J Econ Manage Strat. 2021;30:203227. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
203
Received: 24 June 2018
|
Revised: 8 July 2020
|
Accepted: 8 July 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12395
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Persistent and snap decisionmaking
Tomoya Tajika
Department of Law and Economics,
Hokusei Gakuen University, Oyachinishi
231, Sapporo, Japan
Correspondence
Tomoya Tajika, Department of Law and
Economics, Hokusei Gakuen University,
Oyachinishi 231, Sapporo 0048631,
Japan.
Email: t-tajika@hokusei.ac.jp
Abstract
To avoid unfavorable inferences about her ability, an expert might cling to her
original opinion and ignore valuable new information in formulating sub-
sequent opinions. Conceivably, the expert might decline an initial opportunity
to offer an opinion, delaying the opinion formation until more accurate in-
formation has arrived. However, we show that reputational concerns often
lead an expert to express an opinion at the first opportunity, thereby making a
snap decision.
1|INTRODUCTION
It is widely observed that experts often cling to their original opinion and that such consistency is valued by others.
1
For
example, when a politician makes a statement, it is often seen as a pledge and it is difficult for her to renege on it
without being subject to criticism. Likewise, economists who predict economic trends that are inconsistent with their
previous predictions tend not to be trusted. However, remaining consistent could lead an expert to ignore valuable new
information in formulating subsequent opinions, which often results in bad outcomes.
Many studies examine reputation concern as a force driving consistent behavior (Falk & Zimmermann, 2017;
Li, 2007; Trueman, 1990). In these studies, an expert recommends a choice to an evaluator. The expert has two
opportunities to make a recommendation and, before each opportunity, she receives an independent signal conditional
on the true state of the world. The accuracy of the signals positively correlates with the expert's ability, and this
accuracy increases over time, such that the second signal is more accurate than the first. The expert has reputational
concerns about her ability. In this setting, although a recommendation based on the second signal is preferable for the
evaluator, the expert has an incentive to cling to the recommendation based on the first. This is because an expert with
high abilities would receive highly accurate signals and is less likely to receive inconsistent signals. Hence, the expert
behaves consistently to convey the impression that she received consistent signals because she has high abilities.
Although this explanation is intuitive, one may argue that if consistent behavior is inevitable and leads to a less
valuable recommendation, the expert would remain silent during the initial opportunity to avoid revealing any in-
consistency between the received signals. If this is accurate, unless the expert is forced to make a decision at the initial
opportunity, such consistent behavior resulting in less valuable recommendations would not be observed. In the leading
example, the politician should be careful not to commit herself in a speech because she is better off waiting for
additional information, rather than declaring an intention immediately. However, in reality, people often make hasty
decisions. Nutt (2002) discusses how hasty decisionmaking is a major cause of poor decisions using several case studies
of companies. Consider the following case as an example. Shell UK decided to undertake a deepsea disposal of a spar (a
floating oil storage facility). Before the disposal process began, Greenpeace activists began a public campaign opposing
it, which damaged Shell UK's public image, and forced it to find another way to dispose of the spar. As Nutt (2002)
discusses, the Shell officials did not need to rush in making their decision and could have waited until a public debate
about the best disposal method had occurred.
In this study, we seek to answer the question of why experts convey their earlier opinions rather than waiting for
new information, even when it is well known that this leads them to seek unproductive consistency of behavior, which,
in turn, leads to bad outcomes. In our model, as in previous studies, the expert has two opportunities to make a
recommendation. However, this study takes a further step by examining a case where the expert has two options during
the first opportunity; that is, the expert can either reveal or conceal the information about the signal that she has
received at the initial opportunity. We find a sufficient condition under which the expert has an incentive to reveal the
information during the first opportunity, even if it leads to unproductively consistent behavior. Therefore, even when
the expert is not forced to make a decision at the initial opportunity, consistent behavior can be observed. We refer to
the behavior of breaking silence during the first opportunity and ensuring consistent behavior subsequently as snap
decisionmaking.
The intuition is as follows. The expert considers that by remaining silent during the first period, the evaluator will
believe that the expert's final decision is based on the second signal. Conversely, if the expert makes a decision during
the first period and employs the strategy of behaving consistently, the evaluator will believe that the expert's decision is
based on the first signal. If the expert waits for a more accurate signal and matches her recommendation to the true
state, this will be attributed partly to the improvement of the signal and less to the expert's ability than is the case with
acting on the first signal. By contrast, if the recommendation does not match the state when the expert acts on the
second signal, this is attributed to ability more than is the case with the first signal. Therefore, if the expert remains
silent, her ability is discounted regardless of whether her recommendation matches the state. This reveals the advantage
of snap decisionmaking.
By contrast, if the expert remains silent initially, her ultimate recommendation is more likely to match the true state
than is the case under snap decisionmaking. Because the expert's reputation is higher when her recommendation
matches the state, this indicates the disadvantage of snap decisionmaking.
In our model, we find that under symmetric information between the expert and evaluator concerning the expert's
ability, if the expert's utility function for the assessment is strictly convex
2
and some additional assumptions are
satisfied, an equilibrium with snap decisionmaking exists, which results in higher expected utility than does remaining
silent. Conversely, there is also an equilibrium where the expert reveals no information about the first signal, and
makes an ultimate recommendation based only on the second signal.
3
However, making a snap decision results in
higher utility than does remaining silent and, thus, there is an incentive to reveal the first signal if this is possible. This
implies that the equilibrium revealing no information about the first signal violates a natural equilibrium selection
criterion, called the neologismproofness (Farrell, 1993). In this sense, the snap decision is the unique prediction of our
model.
Our study suggests that, focusing on the neologismproofequilibria,evenwhentheexpertcanremainsilent,
she may decide to engage in unnecessary snap decisionmaking, leading to a poor decision. To avoid such
unproductive recommendations, our study suggests that the client should not only refrain from listening to
earlier opinions but also silence the expert during the first period by imposing a cost. For example, in the context
of decisionmaking in organizations, creating a norm that encourages deliberation may be a solution. In political
contexts, electorates should criticize politicians if they comment on a future political decision without waiting
for new information. Conversely, an intentionally noncommittal (and thus ambiguous) statement should be
praised.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2reviews the related literature. In Section 3, we explain
our model. Section 4addresses the case where the expert is forced to recommend a choice in each period and provides a
sufficient condition under which the expert behaves consistently. In Section 5, we analyze the case in which the expert
can remain silent in the first period. Section 6includes several extensions for analyzing the consistent behavior, and
Section 7draws conclusions. All proofs appear in the appendices.
2|RELATIONSHIP TO THE LITERATURE
Reputation concern distorts an expert's decisionmaking.
4
The relation between reputation concern and persistency in
behaviors has been investigated by several studies, such as Kanodia, Bushman, and Dickhaut (1989), Trueman (1990),
Boot (1992), Prendergast and Stole (1996), Levy (2004), Majumdar and Mukand (2004), Ferreira and Resende (2007), Li
(2007), Sabourian and Sibert (2009), and Falk and Zimmermann (2017). Except for Prendergast and Stole (1996), these
studies deal with binarystate cases, as in our model. Prendergast and Stole (1996) deal with a continuous state case in
which the true state and signals are drawn from normal distributions. They show that the reputationconcerned expert
becomes conservative over time.
5
204
|
TAJIKA

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT