Peers and offender decision‐making

AuthorE. M. Hoeben,K. J. Thomas
Date01 November 2019
Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1745-9133.12462
DOI: 10.1111/1745-9133.12462
RESEARCH ARTICLE
PEERS AND OFFENDER DECISION-MAKING
Peers and offender decision-making
E. M. Hoeben1K. J. Thomas2
1University at Albany,SUNY
2University of Colorado—Boulder
Correspondence
E.M.Hoeben, School of Criminal Justice,
Universityat Albany, State Universityof
NewYork (SUNY), 135 WesternAvenue,
Albany,NY 12222.
Email:ehoeben@albany.edu
Wewould like to thank Frank Weerman, Jean-
Louisvan Gelder, the editor of this special issue
GregPogarsky, and the anonymous reviewerfor
their valuablecomments and suggestions. We
alsog ratefullyacknowledge the contributions
oft he attendees of the symposium on decision-
makingat t he Universityat Albany (April
19and 20, 2018), and of the attendees at t he
plenary session at the Annual meeting of the
American Society of Criminology in Atlanta
(November16, 2018).
Research Summary: Offender decision-making generally
occurs in social context. In this article, we discuss the
potential for integrating insights on peer processes and
decision-making processes to advance our understanding
on the decision to engage in crime. In particular, we address
the developmental and situational influence of peers on
perceptions, preferences, and dual-systems processing. We
contribute to this literature by elaborating on situational
peer processes and discuss the ways in which peers can
affect decision-making through their mere presence as well
as through their active involvement as instigators, conver-
sational partners, and co-offenders.
Policy Implications: Programs to effectivelyreduce cr ime
and delinquency require a holistic approach that takes into
account the interdependency between internal and external
factors that impact behavior.The pur pose of this article was
to detail how our understanding of two prominent explana-
tions of crime —peer influence and rational choice—can
mutually benefit from such integration.
KEYWORDS
offender decision-making, peer influence
When adolescents engage in delinquent conduct, they generally do so in the presence of peers
(Bernasco, Ruiter, Bruinsma, Pauwels, & Weerman, 2013; Reiss, 1988; Van der Laan, Blom, &
Kleemans, 2009; Warr, 1996; Weerman, Bernasco, Bruinsma, & Pauwels, 2015). There is increasing
evidence that these peers impact delinquency in part by affecting an actor’s decision calculus
concerning the anticipated consequences of crime. For example, research has shown that the presence
of peers both lowers one’s expectations about the risks associated with crime (McGloin & Thomas,
2016a) and makes individuals more tolerant of such risk (Chein, Albert, O’Brien, Uckert, & Steinberg,
2011; Defoe, Dubas, Figner, & Van Aken, 2015; Gardner & Steinberg, 2005; O’Brien, Albert, Chein,
Criminology & Public Policy. 2019;18:759–784. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/capp © 2019 American Society of Criminology 759
760 HOEBEN AND THOMAS
& Steinberg, 2011; Vinokur, 1971). Still, despite the growing attention to this topic, work on the inter-
dependence of offender decision-making remains both theoretically and empirically underdeveloped.
Generally, the peer literature tends to concentrate on group processes external to the decision-maker,
whereas the decision-making literature tends to concentrate on internal cognitive processes—that is,
the perceptions and weighing of the benefits, costs, and risks associated with crime. To date, these
two prominent areas of criminological inquiry have developed relatively independent of one another.
The aim here is to provide an integrative—albeit not exhaustive—account of various ways in which
peers can affect offending decisions. Wefirst begin with a brief discussion of the literatures on offender
decision-making and peer influence that have developedindependently of one another. We then discuss
three prominent examples in which peers and decision-making have been combined in the extant lit-
erature: (1) the interdependency of human choice, (2) differential susceptibility to peer influence, and
(3) social influences on perceptual updating of risks, costs, and rewards. Throughout this discussion,
we highlight how these three perspectives haveser vedto advance our understanding of both peer influ-
ence and offender decision-making. In the remainder of the article, we discuss how integrating insights
from the decision-making literature can help advance both normative (Akers, 1998; Sutherland, 1947)
and situational theories of peer influence (Osgood, Wilson, O’Malley, Bachman, & Johnston, 1996;
Warr, 2002) and, further, how such insights can be used to help integrate these mechanisms that are
often viewed as competing (Haynie & Osgood, 2005; Hoeben & Weerman,2016; Thomas & McGloin,
2013). Put simply, we argue that peers can affect perceptions and preferences through socialization in
the long term as well as through situational factors in the short term.
1OFFENDER DECISION-MAKING
The literature on offender decision-making is predominantly situated in rational choice theory (Becker,
1968; Smith, 1976/1761) and has emphasized cost–benefit analysis as a core mechanism for explaining
crime. Traditionally, offending decisions are viewed as a function of two distinct, yet interdependent,
components.
The first component comprises the perceptions of the anticipated risks, costs, and benefits of the
act under consideration. Risk of crime is generally conceptualized as the probability of detection (i.e.,
certainty of arrest). The costs of crime can include the formal costs imposed through legal sanctions
from the criminal justice system (i.e., severity of punishment), self-imposed costs such as feelings
of shame and guilt, and socially imposed costs such as embarrassment or disapproval by family and
friends (Grasmick & Bursik, 1990; Paternoster, 1989). The benefits of crime include material elements
obtained when the act is completed without detection (e.g., stolen goods, monetary returns), psychic
benefits, such as the thrill derived from engaging in the act of crime (Becker, 1968; Katz, 1988), and
“social benefits” such as status among peers (Matsueda, Kreager, & Huizinga, 2006).
The second component of decision-making is the weight that individuals place on these anticipated
risks, costs, and benefits (i.e., the marginal (dis)utilities, preferences). Not all risks, costs, and benefits
carry equal weight in the decision-making process for different individuals (i.e., between individual)
or for the same individual over time (i.e., within individual; Paternoster & Bushway, 2009). In this way,
two individuals who both believe there is a 40% chance of arrest risk may act differently if one views
40% as acceptable and the other as too precarious. Thus, individuals will have preferences regarding
which rewards they value over others, or regarding which costs are more important to avoid com-
pared with other costs. Part of the differences in weights placed on specific costs and rewards can
be a function of individual preferences for various factors, such as time and risk. Time preferences, in
classic economic terms, capture the trade-off between immediate consumption and consumption in the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT