Peer Evaluation: Incentives and Coworker Relations

Published date01 March 2016
AuthorJoeri Sol
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12134
Date01 March 2016
Peer Evaluation: Incentives and Coworker Relations
JOERI SOL
Amsterdam Business School
University of Amsterdam
Amsterdam, Noord-Holland
j.sol@uva.nl
In many workplaces, coworkers have the best information about each other’s efforts. This paper
studies a principal who only observes the joint output by two limitedly liable agents, while agents
receive signals about each other’s effort levels. The principal attempts to exploit this information
through peer evaluation; agents are asked to report their signal and may receive a bonus for
being evaluated positively. Lying aversion ascertains that truthful evaluation is possible, while
interpersonal relations between colleagues give an incentive to misreport. This paper shows that
peer evaluation gives an incentive for effort, even when the evaluations are not truthful. The peer
evaluation bonus is constrained by more intensive coworker relations. Still, the optimal contract
always includes a peer evaluation bonus, sometimes complemented with a team bonus. Coworker
relations have nonmonotonic effects on profits in the optimal contract.
1. Introduction
In many employment relations, managers lack information about employees’ individual
effort or performance; for example, in highly interdependent work teams, with work on
location, or in case of experts. In an attempt to obtain a more complete picture of em-
ployee performance, many firms have turned to multisource feedback; in business better
known as 360evaluations. A 360evaluation can include performance assessments by
subordinates, peers, supervisors, customers, or other stakeholders. According to survey
data, about 90% of Fortune 1000 firms use some form of multisource feedback, often in-
cluding evaluation by peers (Edwards and Ewen, 1996). Moreover, in many companies
peer evaluation schemes partially determine personnel decisions regarding promotions
and performance pay (Bohl, 1996).1
Evaluation by peers has intuitive appeal when employees have valuable informa-
tion about one another’s performance. However, when seen from an economic theory
perspective, the widespread use of peer evaluation is less obvious. A major concern
is that employees may benefit from providing the employer with invalid performance
evaluations of their colleagues. For instance, employees can provide invalid ratings so
as to help their friends, hurt their competitors, or “game the system” through collusion
(Edwards and Ewen, 1996; Kozlowski et al., 1998). In line with this, Tsui and Barry
(1986) find that performance evaluations are more lenient when raters experience more
I gratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions by Daniel Arce, Josse Delfgaauw, Robert Dur, Amihai
Glazer, Vladimir Karamychev, Navin Kartik, Mirjam van Praag, Paul Steffens, and seminar audiences at
Erasmus University and at University of Amsterdam, and participants of the “Social Relations and Incentives
in the Workplace” workshop in Rotterdamand the IMEBE 2011 in Barcelona.
1. Bohl (1996) finds that one-fifth of 750 surveyed companies reports to use peer evaluations, of which 90%
includes the peer evaluation in personnel decisions. Similarly,in a survey among 280 firms, roughly one-fifth
of the firms have adopted some form of peer evaluation (Antonioni, 1996).
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 1, Spring 2016, 56–76
Peer Evaluation 57
personal affect toward the ratee.2Love (1981) even asserts that: “The most common
rationale given by organizational personnel for avoiding the use of peer assessment is
that it is simply a ‘popularity contest’.” (p. 451). This paper develops a formal agency
model so as to study when and how peer evaluation should be used under different
intensities of coworker relations.
I study peer evaluation in a model of team production by two homogeneous agents,
who are protected by limited liability. The production suffers from a pure moral hazard
problem; that is, the principal is unable to distinguish individual inputs, and can only
offer a team bonus for output. A team bonus results in inefficiently low effort levels,
since limited liability makes the budget breaking solution infeasible. Agents, on the
other hand, receive a signal about their colleague’s effort provision. The principal can
attempt to gather the information from these signals by employing peer evaluation, and
consequently attempt to offer more efficient incentives. A bonus is paid to those agents
that receive a positive evaluation report. As a starting point, I assume ideal circumstances
for peer evaluation: Agents have an aversion toward lying about their signal. A small
cost of lying is sufficient to ensure truthful evaluations, as the agents’ reports only
affect the payoff of their colleague.3Peer evaluation motivates agents to exert effort
so as to increase the likelihood that their coworker receives a positive signal and rates
performance accordingly. Under these ideal circumstances, peer evaluation outperforms
a team bonus; in fact, peer evaluation performs as well as individual incentives would.
Next, I allow for interpersonal relations between colleagues, either good or bad.
Social preferences can give agents an incentive to lie about their signal; that is, coworker
relations cause a (dis)likeability bias in the evaluations. In case, the internalized utility
from a bonus to a friend outweighs the cost of lying, agents in good relationships give
positive evaluations regardless of their signal. Likewise, agents in bad relationships
may begrudge their colleague a bonus and lie upon receiving a positive signal. The
anticipation of invalid peer evaluation still provides incentives for effort, as agents
also internalize of a colleague’s lying costs. For example, friends who give each other
positive evaluations irrespective of performance still provide effort so as to limit the
expected lying costs of the befriended colleague. However, there is only a limited range
of parameter values for which nontruthful peer evaluation is optimal, and exclusive to
workplaces with bad coworker relations.
The principal can ensure truthful evaluation by adjusting the bonus for peer eval-
uations downward, such that coworker relations do not affect the evaluation decision.
In other words, social preferences constrain the effectiveness of peer evaluation. Never-
theless, the optimal contract always includes peer evaluation. The principal will com-
plement incentives for effort by including a team bonus in case peer evaluation becomes
severely constrained. The combination of peer evaluation and a team bonus gives an
interesting comparative static result regarding the effect of coworker relations on prof-
its. The effectiveness of the team bonus increases with better coworker relations, as
coworker relations mitigate incentives to free ride on a colleague. Peer evaluations suf-
fer from more pronounced coworker relations, through the earlier discussed likability
bias. Taken together, coworker relations have nonmonotonic effects on profits.
2. Similar significant correlations between likeability and leniency in peer evaluation can be found in
Sonnentag (1998) and Love (1981). Antonioni and Park (2001) show that peer evaluations suffer more from
such a likeability bias than traditional performance evaluations.
3. This paper studies how peer evaluation may suffer under different intensities of coworker relations.
In doing so, it abstracts from a number of other motivations that may lead to invalid evaluations, such as
competition and collusion between workers. I come back to these motivations in the concluding remarks.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT