Options in Compensation: Promises and Pitfalls

AuthorCLAUS MUNK,HANS FRIMOR,CHRISTIAN RIIS FLOR
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12049
Date01 June 2014
Published date01 June 2014
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12049
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 52 No. 3 June 2014
Printed in U.S.A.
Options in Compensation: Promises
and Pitfalls
CHRISTIAN RIIS FLOR,
HANS FRIMOR,
AND CLAUS MUNK
Received 2 November 2012; accepted 16 December 2013
ABSTRACT
We derive the optimal compensation contract in a principal–agent setting
in which outcome is used to provide incentives for both effort and risky in-
vestments. To motivate investment, optimal compensation entails rewards for
high as well as low outcomes, and it is increasing at the mean outcome to mo-
tivate effort. If rewarding low outcomes is infeasible, compensation consisting
of stocks and options is a near-efficient means of overcoming the manager’s
induced aversion to undertaking risky investments, whereas stock compensa-
tion is not. However, stock plus option compensation may induce excessively
risky investments, and capping pay can be important in curbing such behav-
ior.
1. Introduction
An important element in corporate governance is the set of mechanisms
that serve to influence management decisions when ownership and con-
trol are separate. One important and hotly debated mechanism is the com-
pensation of managers. The current crisis has been blamed on common
pay practices, which allegedly have led to greediness, excessive risk-taking,
and short-sightedness in the financial sector, and the political systems in
the United States and the European Union have responded by regulating
University of Southern Denmark; Aarhus University; Copenhagen Business School.
Accepted by Haresh Sapra. We appreciate comments from an anonymous referee, Anil
Arya, Peter Ove Christensen, Joel Demski, John Fellingham, Steven Huddart, Brian Mitten-
dorf, and Richard Young as well as participants at the 2011 Chicago-Minnesota Accounting
Theory Conference.
703
Copyright C, University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2014
704 C.R.FLOR,H.FRIMOR,AND C.MUNK
executive compensation.1The regulation ranges from increased disclosure
requirements and “say-on-pay” votes over mandatory deferral of compensa-
tion and performance-based vesting to capping of bonuses and an outright
ban on options. An important objective is to balance incentives for risk-
taking either by ensuring that decision makers share equally in success and
failure or by capping the upside. The regulation has been intensely dis-
puted and especially so the cap on bonuses, while the attempts to ensure
that decision makers share in failure have received less attention.
In an agency setting with induced moral hazard, we show that capping
of bonuses can be optimal, whereas forcing managers to share equally in
failure and success in general cannot. Specifically, we show that options—
often combined with stocks—closely resemble the optimal contracts de-
signed to overcome a manager’s aversion to undertaking risky investments.
We demonstrate that the expected payoff generated under such compensa-
tion is often very close to the payoff generated under the optimal contract.
However, we also show that option compensation can be highly inefficient.
The inefficiency arises from the fact that option compensation can give the
agent an incentive to take on excessive risk, and an obvious question is how
to curb such incentives. We find that restricting compensation to the class
of linear contracts to consist of, for example, fixed salary plus restricted
stock, can be a very costly solution. We show that an alternative and much
more efficient solution is to use option compensation where total remu-
neration is capped. That is, the agent is not additionally compensated for
extreme outcomes, so the upside of the contract is removed.
We employ a hidden action model or principal–agent model where a
risk-neutral principal (representing the shareholders of the company) mo-
tivates an agent (the manager) to undertake hidden actions through com-
pensation based on a measure of performance (e.g., earnings or stock
price). We extend the typical principal–agent setting with unobservable ef-
fort by assuming that, in addition to effort affecting the mean, the agent
decides on risky investments affecting both the mean and the variance of
the outcome. The agent has no direct preferences over investments, but,
as compensation is used to induce preferences over effort, the investment
decision is subject to induced moral hazard. When hidden actions affect
only the mean, the optimal compensation scheme is increasing and con-
cave in outcome, and consequently compensation involving stock options
is inefficient. If investments must also be motivated and investments affect
variance, then the optimal unrestricted compensation scheme has a “short
1See, for example, Blinder [2009] and Bebchuck and Spamann [2009] as well as the mem-
orandum “Interagency Guidance on Sound Incentive Compensation Policies” by the U.S. De-
partment of the Treasury and the European Union Commission proposal COM(2009)0362
available, respectively, at http://www.occ.gov/news-issuances/federal-register/75fr36395.pdf
and http://www.ipex.eu/ipex/cms/home/Documents/doc˙COM20090362FIN. Further,see,
for example, Cassidy [2002] and Madrick [2003] regarding the alleged role of stock-based
compensation in earlier corporate scandals.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT