Money secrets: How does trade secret legal protection affect firm market value? Evidence from the uniform trade secret act

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2533
Published date01 April 2017
AuthorRaffaele Conti,Francesco Castellaneta,Aleksandra Kacperczyk
Date01 April 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 834–853 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 19 July 2016 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2533
Received 15 May 2015;Final revision received30 March 2016
MONEY SECRETS: HOW DOES TRADE SECRET
LEGAL PROTECTION AFFECT FIRM MARKET VALUE?
EVIDENCE FROM THE UNIFORM TRADE SECRET ACT
FRANCESCO CASTELLANETA,1RAFFAELE CONTI,1and ALEKSANDRA
KACPERCZYK2*
1Catolica Lisbon School of Business and Economics, Lisbon, Portugal
2MIT Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.A.
Research summary: Weinvestigate the impact of trade secret legalprotection on rm market value
in the context of acquisitions. On one hand, market value may increase because tradesecret assets
become better protected fromrivals. On the other hand, market value may decrease because trade
secret protection reduces information about the target and its competitors available to potential
buyers, increasing uncertainty about its value. Buyers will discount their offers in expectation of
being compensated for riskier deals. Using a sample of private equity investments in the United
States, we nd that trade secret protection has a positive effectin industries with high mobility of
knowledge workers, but a negative effect in industries with (1) high resource– value uncertainty
and (2) high poor-investment risk.
Managerial summary: We argue that an increase in trade secret legal protection might not
unequivocally benet rm owners when selling their business. A stronger trade secret protection
increases the market value of rms in industries with high workers’ mobility, but it decreases
the market value of rms in industries with uncertain resource value and/or high risk of
poor-acquisition investments. Based on the contingent effect of trade secretprotection, companies
may want to adjust their strategicdecisions, including where to locate or relocate, based in part on
whether they will derive benets or suffer losses when trade secrets are better protected. Finally,
our study should help policymakers understand more fully the economic impact of government
policies associated with trade secrets. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
The strategy literature has long argued that valuable
resources are key for rm sustainable competi-
tive advantage (e.g., Barney, 1991; Mahoney
and Pandian, 1992; Rumelt, 1984). In partic-
ular, as world economies become increasingly
knowledge-intensive, outperforming rivals depends
more and more on rms developing proprietary
Keywords: trade secrecy; market value; legal environment;
buyout; natural experiment
*Correspondence to: Aleksandra (Olenka) Kacperczyk, Asso-
ciate Professor of Technological Innovation, Entrepreneurship,
and Strategic Management MIT Sloan School of Manage-
ment 100 Main St., E62-484; Cambridge, MA 02142. E-mail:
olenka@mit.edu
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
knowledge (Grant, 1996; Kogut and Zander,
1992). Yet, the resulting competitive advantage
is hardly sustainable if rms fail to protect their
know-how by minimizing the threat of imitation by
rivals (e.g., Barney, 1991; Mahoney and Pandian,
1992; Rumelt, 1984). In this respect, the legal
appropriability regime— the extent to which the
legal system protects and enforces property rights
on intangible resources— plays a crucial role.
A large body of work on intellectual property
rights (IPRs) has established that a strong legal
IPR protection mitigates the risk of imitation
of valuable know-how, which ensures that rms
can appropriate a greater share of returns from
their intangible resources and so increases their
market value (Teece, 1986). However, the extant
accounts have mainly focused on the role of patents
How Does Trade Secret Legal Protection Affect Firm Market Value? 835
(e.g., Cockburn and Griliches, 1988; Hall, Jaffe,
and Trajtenberg, 2005), which require complete
disclosure of the underlying knowledge resource
and therefore facilitate the assessment process.
Insights gleaned from this literature might not
extend to other forms of IPR protection, such as
trade secrets, whose owners are “rewarded for
keeping information away from the public for
an unlimited duration” (Risch, 2007: 11).
Hence, we ask: How does the legal protection
of trade secrets affect rm market value?1Trade
secrets— encompassing information on marketing
data, manufacturing know-how, chemical formulae,
and technical data— are “arguably the most impor-
tant and most heavily litigated intellectual prop-
erty rights” (Risch, 2007: 1) and are considered
the “crown jewels” of a rm’s intellectual capital
(Jorda, 2007). Yet,researchers have not linked trade
secret protection to rm value, eventhough its effect
has been documented with respect to employee
mobility (Png and Samila, 2015) and to a rm’s
incentives to innovate (Png, 2015) and to cluster
(Fosfuri and Rønde, 2004). Toll this gap, we focus
on the market for corporate control, which rep-
resents strategic factor markets where bundles of
resources are traded and the competitive advantage
of rms is monetized (e.g., Barney, 1991; Capron
and Shen, 2007; Shen and Reuer, 2005).
Against this background, we propose that trade
secret protection may affect rm market value in
two opposite ways, generating a paradox worth
exploring. On one hand, a stronger protection of a
rm’s trade secrets might limit the outward ow of
information about trade secrets to competitors and
thus lessen the risk of misappropriation and imita-
tion. Hence, the target’s value might increase. On
the other hand, trade secret protection might limit
the amount of rm-specic information available to
potential buyers and thus increase the information
asymmetries between buyers and sellers. Lack of
information increases uncertainty about the value
of the target rm, motivating buyers to discount
their offers as a compensation for pursuing a more
uncertain and riskier deal. Hence, the target’s value
might decrease. In sum, trade secret protection
may be a double-edged sword for the target rm,
creating advantageous information asymmetries
vis-à-vis its competitors as well as disadvantageous
1Wewill refer to “trade secret(s) legal protection” as “trade secret
protection” for simplicity.
information asymmetries vis-à-vis its potential
buyers.
To explore these seemingly contradictory argu-
ments, we examine the heterogeneous effects of
trade secret protection on the target’s market value.
We propose that the direction of the trade secret
protection effect might depend on the target’sindus-
try characteristic. First, an increase in trade secret
protection may have a positive effect in indus-
tries where the cross-rm mobility of knowledge
workers is higher, because a strong protection of
trade secrets constrains the amount of knowledge
that former employees may transfer to competitors
(Fosfuri and Rønde, 2004; Png and Samila, 2015).
Second, an increase in trade secret protection may
have a negative effect when the target’s industry
exhibits (1) substantial resource– value uncertainty
and hence detailed information on the target’sintan-
gible assets becomes crucial for a proper target eval-
uation (Barney, 1991) and (2) high risk of making
a poor— or “lemon”— investment, especially if a
stronger trade secret protection hampers the assess-
ment of target rms (Akerlof, 1970; Coff, 1999).
Assessing the impact of trade secret protection
on rm market value is empirically challenging
because such protection might be endogenous with
respect to rm value. For example, policymakers
might enact a law enhancing trade secret protection
to improve the state economic conditions— which
would affect local rms’ value— or the law might
result from lobbying efforts by state companies.
Hence, a research design that facilitates a clean
causal estimate is central to understanding the
impact of trade secret protection on rm market
value.
We address this empirical challenge by exploit-
ing a quasi-natural experiment provided by the
enactment of statutes based on the Uniform Trade
Secret Act (UTSA), which occurred in 46 U.S.
states between 1975 and 2008. In this period,
trade secret protection increased dramatically (Png,
2015). Important for our identication strategy,
accounts of the political economy of these reforms
suggest that their enactment was exogenous to state
economic and political characteristics, and was not
the result of any lobbying effort (Png, 2015). Specif-
ically, we test our theory on a sample of 1,890 U.S.
rms managed by 132 privateequity (PE) rms. The
PE market is an advantageous empirical setting for
testing our theory. PE rms are investors that make
prots through buyouts— buying and reselling the
control of private companies— overrelatively short
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 834–853 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT