Merchants of doubt: Corporate political action when NGO credibility is uncertain

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12338
AuthorThomas P. Lyon,Mireille Chiroleu‐Assouline
Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:439461. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems © 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
439
Received: 3 January 2018
|
Revised: 27 June 2019
|
Accepted: 16 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12338
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Merchants of doubt: Corporate political action when NGO
credibility is uncertain
Mireille ChiroleuAssouline
1
|
Thomas P. Lyon
2
1
Paris School of Economics, University of
Paris 1 PanthéonSorbonne, Paris, France
2
Business Economics and Public Policy,
Ross School of Business, University of
Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan
Correspondence
Thomas P. Lyon, Ross School of Business,
701 Tappan St., University of Michigan,
Ann Arbor, MI 48109.
Email: tplyon@umich.edu
Funding information
French National Research Agency,
Grant/Award Number: ANR15CE05
000801; Investissements dAvenir
Program of the French government,
Grant/Award Number: ANR17EURE001
Abstract
The literature on special interest groups emphasizes two main influence
channels: campaign contributions and informational lobbying. We introduce a
third channel: providing information about the credibility of political rivals. In
particular, nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) often aim to communicate
scientific knowledge to policymakers, but industrybacked groups often attempt
to undermine their credibility. We extend a standard signaling model of
interestgroup lobbying to include fixed costs of policymaker action and show
that these costs make possible two mechanisms for creating doubt about the
value of policy action. The first uses Bayesian persuasion to suggest the NGO
may be a noncredible radical. The second involves creating an opposition think
tank (TT) that acts as a possible radical, not a credible moderate. We show that
the TT cannot always implement the Bayesian persuasion benchmark, and we
characterize how optimal TT design varies with exogenous parameters.
KEYWORDS
informational lobbying, nonmarket strategy, persuasion, special interest politics
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D72; D82; L31; Q58
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Political action to regulate externalities, provide public goods and protect public health depends crucially on scientific
knowledge. However, public doubts about the credibility of scientific experts may undermine political support for
regulation. Indeed, Oreskes and Conway (2010) present a series of indepth case studies showing how business groups
whose profits were threatened by regulation sowed doubt about the scientific basis for action. They cover cases
involving the regulation of tobacco, acid rain, the hole in the ozone layer, and climate change. Their central
contribution is to detail how business interests attempted to block or delay legislation, even though the weight of
scientific evidence was against them. In each case, the strategies involved creating uncertainty about the scientific case
for regulation by undermining the credibility of scientists and sciencebased nongovernmental organizations (NGOs).
In fact, a 1969 memo by a tobacco industry executive explained that Doubt is our product since it is the best means of
competing with the body of factthat exists in the minds of the general public.(Oreskes & Conway, 2010, p. 34).
[Correction added after online publication on 14 January 2020: The affiliation of the author Mireille ChiroleuAssoulinehas been corrected from
Centre dEconomie de la Sorbonne, Paris School of Economics, University of Paris 1 PanthéonSorbonne, Paris, Franceto Paris School of
Economics, University of Paris 1 PanthéonSorbonne, Paris, France.]
One common strategy for creating doubt is to attack the character of sciencebased organizations, accusing them of a
political bias that makes their recommendations untrustworthy. Even if there is no evidence to support such an attack, bold
assertions may be enough to create sufficient doubt to damage a scientists reputation. One victim of such attacks was Ben
Santer, recipient of a 1998 MacArthur Foundation geniusgrant and lead author of Chapter 8 of the Second Assessment
Report issued by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). Santer was the target of a 1996 OpEd piece in the
Wall Street Journal that accused him of making changes to the IPCC report to deceive policy makers and the public.(Oreskes
& Conway, 2010, p. 3). The charges were falsehe had simply edited the chapter in response to review comments from fellow
scientistsbut that did not stop Frederick Seitz, chairman of the George C. Marshall Institute, from making them. Seitz, then
85 years old, had had an illustrious career in materials science and solidstate physics. Upon his retirement in 1979, he became
a consultant for the tobacco industry and later the fossil fuel industry, arguing against regulation of secondhand smoke and
global warming. Although Santer and 40 other climate scientists wrote a sharp rebuttal to the Journal, the newspaper edited
the rebuttal heavily and deleted the names of the other 40 signatories, making it appear to be a selfserving response by Santer
alone. The ensuing public war of words was too complicated for most members of the public to parse, and could easily be seen
as just another debate between two sides,each with their own equally valid views. Doubt had been sown.
A second common strategy is for a think tank(TT) to put forward competing scientific expertswhose opinions are
opposed to those of the scientists calling for policy action. This is a tactic that has become increasingly common since
Anthony Fisher created the Atlas Network in 1981 with the intention to litter the world with freemarket think tanks.
(Djelic, 2014).
1
For example, in 1989 the Marshall Institute issued a white paperon global warming that argued any
warming was caused by solar activity, not greenhouse gas emissions. Although the paper was not written by climate scientists
and had not been subjected to peer review, the Institute contacted the White House and was invited to present the report to
members of the Council of Economic Advisers, the Office of Management and Budget, and other highlevel executive branch
entities. This outreach effort was remarkably effective and had a big impact, stopping the positive momentum that had been
building in the Bush administration.(Oreskes & Conway, 2010, p. 186). This was hardly the only example of counter
lobbying by industryfunded TTs. Indeed, Jacques, Dunlap, and Freeman (2008) study 141 Englishlanguage books that adopt
a skeptical stance on environmental issues and find that 92% of them are associated with conservative TTs. Dunlap and
Jacques (2013) study books denying climate change in particular and find that at least 90% of them do not undergo peer
review. One of the key funders of climate denial efforts was ExxonMobil, which has given over $20 million to sow doubt about
global warming to a wide array of TTs, with the biggest recipient being the Competitive Enterprise Institute with $2 million of
ExxonMobil support (Hoggan & Littlemore, 2009, p. 82). After its support for climate denialists was exposed publicly by
Greenpeace, ExxonMobil cut off funding to the Competitive Enterprise Institute, though it nevertheless continued to donate
over $2 million to other denialists in 2007 (Hoggan & Littlemore, 2009, p. 84).
There is a rich literature in economics and political science on the strategies used by interest groups to influence the
political process. The literature has focused on two main channels of influence: campaign contributions (AustenSmith,
1995, 1998; Bernheim & Whinston, 1986; Cotton, 2009; Groseclose & Snyder, 1996; Kroszner & Stratmann, 1998;
Snyder, 1990) and informational lobbying (Crawford & Sobel, 1982; Krishna & Morgan, 2001; Lohmann, 1995; Potters &
Van Winden, 1992). Grossman and Helpman (2001) provide an excellent overview of both strategies. Recent models
have begun to incorporate both options. For example, Bennedsen and Feldmann (2006) study the choice between
lobbying and campaign contributions; they assume the politician can see whether an interest group invested in
gathering information, so a failure to lobby is informative, and hence there is a tradeoff between lobbying and campaign
contributions, with interest groups specializing in one or the other. Dahm and Porteiro (2008) have a similar model to
Bennedsen and Feldmann, but they assume the politican cannot observe whether an interest group has engaged in
information gathering or not, and hence they find that interest groups invest in both strategies.
In this paper, we introduce a new channel through which an interest group can influence policy: supplying
information about the credibility of political rivals. We develop a model that extends the literature on informational
lobbying (Grossman & Helpman, 2001) to explore the impact of doubtcreation strategies on the public policy process.
We identify conditions under which the creation of doubt can weaken regulatory policy or block its passage altogether.
Because a firm that faces increased costs from regulation is typically not a credible source of information, it may need to
resort to indirect tactics to influence public policy. In particular, we model the two tactics described above, motivated by
recent literature on the role of business in the policy process. First, we model the process of undermining the credibility
of the NGO as a form of Bayesian persuasion, not about the state of the world itself but about the political bias of the
NGO. Second, we model the operations of a think tankthat can provide noisy information about the state of the
world that is contrary to that provided by the NGO. We show that the two mechanisms can be used to produce identical
effects, and we characterize the conditions under which they are effective.
2
440
|
CHIROLEUASSOULINE AND LYON

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT