Matching Capital and Labor

AuthorBINYING LIU,JONATHAN B. BERK,JULES H. BINSBERGEN
Published date01 December 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12542
Date01 December 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2017
Matching Capital and Labor
JONATHAN B. BERK, JULES H. van BINSBERGEN, and BINYING LIU
ABSTRACT
We establish an important role for the firm by studying capital reallocation decisions
of mutual fund firms. The firm’s decision to reallocate capital among its mutual fund
managers adds at least $474,000 a month, which amounts to over 30% of the total
value added of the industry. We provide evidence that this additional value added
results from the firm’s private information about the skill of its managers. The firm
captures this value because investors reward the firm following a capital reallocation
decision by allocating additional capital to the firm’s funds.
WE DEMONSTRATE THAT AN IMPORTANT ROLE of a firm in the mutual fund sector is
to efficiently match capital to skill. In a world with perfectly rational players,
no information asymmetries, and no other frictions, the role of a mutual fund
firm would be irrelevant because investors themselves would efficiently allocate
their own capital among managers. In reality, mutual fund executives play a
very important role in capital allocation. We find that a decision to increase a
portfolio manager’s assets under management (AUM) leads to an increase in
the manager’s productivity as measured by value added. Similarly, a decision
to reduce a manager’s responsibilities by taking away assets also leads to an
increase in value added. Indeed, at a minimum, the decision to reallocate capital
to a manager adds, on average, $474,000 per manager per month, implying
that the firm is responsible for at least 30% of the total value added of the
average manager. Mutual fund firms therefore appear to add substantial value
by intermediating between investors and managers and thereby efficiently
matching capital to skill.
We further find that investors are unable to match the firm’s capital realloca-
tion decisions themselves. We hypothesize that this is due to the significant in-
formational advantage that mutual fund executives have relative to investors.
Jonathan Berk is with Stanford University and the NBER, Jules van Binsbergen is with the
Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania and the NBER, and Binying Liu is with the
Hong Kong University of Science and Technology. None of the authors have any relevant or ma-
terial financial interests that relate to the research described in this paper. We thank the Acting
Editor, David Robinson; two anonymous referees; Anat Admati; Peter DeMarzo; Daniel Ferreira;
Ravi Jagannathan; Dirk Jenter; Francisco Perez-Gonzalez; Paul Pfleiderer; Anamaria Piescha-
con; Jonathan Reuter; Michael Roberts; Paulo Volpin; and seminar participants at Georgia State
University, the University of Chicago, Oxford University, University of Warwick, Baruch College,
Stanford University,UCLA, the University of Maryland, Wharton, University of New South Wales,
University of Sydney, University of Melbourne, the Adam Smith Workshop, the SFS Cavalcade,
and the NBER Corporate Finance Meetings, for helpful comments and suggestions.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12542
2467
2468 The Journal of Finance R
In particular, firm executives know every trade a manager makes, as well as
trades that the manager chooses not to make. Executives can use this infor-
mation to direct capital away from overfunded managers toward underfunded
managers.
We find support for the informational advantage hypothesis: (1) external
hires that involve a change in AUM do not lead to a detectable change in
future value added, (2) while past performance does explain investor flows,
it does not have much power to explain firm capital reallocation decisions,
and (3) investors respond to these capital reallocation decisions by investing
additional capital in the firm’s funds. We also find that the capital realloca-
tion decision adds more value for young managers, in line with the hypothesis
that the firm’s advantage derives from its access to superior information about
managerial ability. These results are consistent with the view that firm ex-
ecutives use factors not easily observable to people outside the firm to make
personnel decisions (Alchian and Demsetz (1972)). They are also consistent
with investors trusting mutual fund firms to make sound financial decisions
on their behalf (Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2015)), and so when they see
these firms making a managerial change, they respond by investing additional
capital.
Although a large body of evidence demonstrates the importance of the firm’s
informational advantage in assigning workers to jobs and (thereby) determin-
ing compensation, there is little evidence on whether firms also use their su-
perior information to determine an employee’s job scope. Our results imply
that, by correctly determining how much responsibility to give an employee in
a particular job, firms add considerable value. Consequently, the documented
wage gains that result from internal job assignments likely not only result from
the productivity gains from correctly matching jobs to workers, but also from
correctly assigning worker responsibility within a job.
Many questions pertaining to the economics of organizations are difficult
to address because it is often hard to measure employee output directly. An
advantage of our study is that, because the performance of a mutual fund
is public information, employee output is directly observable. A mutual fund
manager has one task—to invest capital on behalf of investors. The return he
generates as well as the amount of capital invested are public information.
The investor’s next-best alternative investment opportunity, an investment in
passively managed index funds, is also observable. By comparing the manager’s
performance against this alternative, we can directly calculate an individual
manager’s productivity, that is, value added. A second advantage of our study
is that mutual fund firms own little physical capital.1Consequently, ownership
rights to capital cannot play an important role in why mutual fund companies
exist or are valuable. Our results therefore imply that other factors, such as
the informational role of the firm, are also important.
1Although the industry is capital-intensive, firms do not own their own capital. Instead, firms
manage capital on behalf of outside investors. That is, capital providers retain full ownership
rights to their capital and can call it back at any time.
Matching Capital and Labor 2469
Although we do not find strong evidence for a behavioral explanation of our
findings, we cannot definitively rule out the possibility that our results derive
at least in part from suboptimal investor behavior. For example, part of the
value that the firm adds could result from investor inattention—firms add
value by paying attention on investors’ behalf. We leave it to future research
to determine the possible importance of this explanation for our results.
In Section I, we describe how our paper relates to the existing literature.
We develop a simple model that formalizes our hypothesis for why firms add
value in Section II. In Section III, we define the value added of firms, funds,
and managers. We describe the data set and provide summary statistics in
Section IV. In Section V, we show that we can reject our null hypothesis that
firm capital reallocation decisions do not add value and, more importantly,
provide a lower bound on the value firms add. In Section VI, we show that
investors respond to these capital allocation decisions by investing additional
capital with the firm, indicating that investors are aware of the value these de-
cisions add. Section VII presents evidence consistent with the hypothesis that
the value the firm adds by reallocating capital derives from the firm’s informa-
tional advantage from observing the quality of its employees. In Section VIII,
we discuss the importance of using value added instead of gross alpha as our
main variable of interest. Finally,in Section IX we provide concluding remarks.
I. Background
The literature on the economics of organizations raises several important
questions about the role of firms. What makes a firm successful? Is it an inher-
ent characteristic of the firm itself, or is it that a successful firm is simply a
collection of particularly talented employees? Why do people choose to work for
firms rather than for themselves? And do personnel decisions within the firm
add to overall firm value?
A large theoretical literature attempts to shed light on these questions (see,
for example, Holmstrom and Tirole (1989), Hart and Moore (1990), Hart (1995),
and Rajan and Zingales (1998)). A key component of modern theories of the firm
is ownership. In a world with incomplete contracting, incomplete information,
and bounded rationality, ex post bargaining power is affected by ownership.
In particular, because they retain control rights, asset owners have inherently
more bargaining power. An important insight of this literature is that firms
exist to ensure that ex ante ownership is concentrated to allow for efficient ex
post outcomes. However, while these theories undoubtedly help explain why
modern firms exist, they cannot explain the existence of an increasingly im-
portant type of firm, namely, a firm that consists almost exclusively of human
capital. These firms have little physical capital other than perhaps some in-
tangible capital such as the firm’s brand name. As a result, a primary reason
for the existence of these types of firms cannot be the assignment of ex post
bargaining rights through asset ownership.
Our paper relates to a growing literature pioneered by Bertrand and Schoar
(2003) that seeks to isolate the productive role of the worker (manager) from

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT