Managerial turnover and entrenchment

Published date01 October 2018
AuthorXi Weng,Zenan Wu
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12248
Date01 October 2018
742 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems J Econ Manage Strat. 2018;27:742–771.
Received: 12 July 2016 Revised: 8 March 2018 Accepted: 22 March 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12248
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Managerial turnover and entrenchment
Zenan Wu1Xi Weng2
1School of Economics, Peking University,
Beijing,China (Email: zenan@pku.edu.cn)
2Guanghua School of Management,
Peking University,Beijing, China
(Email: wengxi125@gsm.pku.edu.cn)
Fundinginformation
SeedFund (School of Economics, Peking
University);Key Laboratory of Mathematical
Economicsand Quantit ativeFinance (Peking
University),Ministry of Education
Abstract
We consider a two-period model in which the success of the firm depends on the
effort of a first-period manager (the incumbent) as well as the effort and ability of
a second-period manager. At the end of the first period, the board receives a noisy
signal of the incumbent manager's ability and decides whether to retain or replace
the incumbent manager. We show that severance pay can be utilized in the optimal
contract to provide a credible commitment to a lenient second-period equilibrium
replacement policy, mitigating the first-period moral hazard problem. Unlike existing
models that aim to rationalize managerial entrenchment, we identify conditions on the
information structure under which both entrenchment and anti-entrenchment emerge
in the optimal contract. Specifically, our model predicts that it is optimal fort heboard
to design a contract to induce entrenchment (respectively, anti-entrenchment) if the
signal regarding the incumbent manager's ability becomes sufficiently uninformative
(respectively, informative).
1INTRODUCTION
Designing compensation schemes in managerial contracts and deciding whether to replace a manager, such as a CEO, are
important firm organization activities. These decisions are linked through the severance agreement, a key component of the
contracts between boards and managers. The severance agreement specifies payments tot he managerupon his forced departure.
Approximately,50% of the CEO compensation contracts implemented between 1994 and 1999 involved some form of severance
agreement (Rusticus, 2006). The percentage of S&P 500 firms that included a severance agreement in their CEO compensation
contracts increased from 20% in 1993 to more than 55% in 2007 (Huang, 2011). In general, a contract with a severance agreement
adds an explicit cost to the board's retention decision and makes replacement more difficult relative to a compensation contract
without such an agreement.
A widely held belief is that CEOs are replaced too infrequently, that is, they become entrenched.1Entrenchment may arise
for many reasons. For example, it may be due to governance failure in the form of a captive board of directors (Hermalin &
Weisbach, 1998; Inderst & Mueller, 2010; Shleifer & Vishny, 1989) or a way to mitigate a moral hazard problem (Almazan
& Suarez, 2003; Casamatta & Guembel, 2010; Manso, 2011). Taylor (2010) makes the first attempt to measure the cost of
entrenchment using a structural model of CEO turnover and finds suggestive evidence of the opposite. In particular, he finds
that boards in large firms fire CEOs with higher frequency than is optimal. We refer to this phenomenon as anti-entrenchment.
We thank a coeditor and two anonymousreferees for very detailed comments that have helped us to significantly improve the paper. Weare deeply indebted to
Hanming Fang and Aislinn Bohren for their guidance and continuous support. We thank DavidDillenberger, Zehao Hu, Navin Kartik, SangMok Lee, Qingmin
Liu, George Mailath, Steven Matthews, Andrew Postlewaite, Xianwen Shi, Wing Suen, Lucian Taylor, and seminar participants at the Chinese Universityof
Hong Kong, Peking University,Renmin University, Shandong University, Shanghai Universityof Finance and Economics, and University of Pennsylvania for
helpful comments and suggestions. Wu acknowledges research support from the Seed Fund (School of Economics, Peking University). Weng acknowledges
support from Key Laboratory of Mathematical Economics and Quantitative Finance (Peking University), Ministry of Education. All remaining errors are our
own.
WU AND WENG 3
743
This finding cannot be rationalized by the existing models on CEO turnover and thus calls for a newmodel to better understand
the determinants of managerial turnover.
This paper investigates how optimal design of the severance agreement influences managerial entrenchment. A manager is
said to be entrenched (or anti-entrenched) if the board retains (fires) him when his expected ability is lower (higher) than that
of a replacement manager. We proposea two-period pr incipal–agentmodel of managerial turnover and identify conditions that
predict the emergence of entrenchment and anti-entrenchment. Formally, weconsider a setup in which the first-period manager
is incentivized by a contract that contains performance-related pay and severance pay. The firm's success depends on the initial
manager's effort, the second-period manager's effort and his ability. Thus, the board faces an ability selection problem and a
period-1 moral hazard problem. After the initial manager exerts effort, the board observes a noncontractible signal regarding
his ability. The board can fire the initial manager by paying the severance pay specified in the contract and hire a replacement
manager.
Severance pay can be utilized in the optimal contract to provide a credible commitment to a lenient period-2 equilibrium
replacement policy, which mitigates the period-1 moral hazard problem and influences the period-2 manager's expected ability.
To see how the use of severance pay can be desirable for the board, it is useful to consider a contract with zero severance pay,
under which the board is able to dismiss the incumbent at will. Because the wage is only paid at the end of the second period,
the board will always preferto fire t he first-period manager if he is of the same ability as the replacement manager,so as to avoid
paying the higher promised wage. Such a zero-severance-pay contract, however, may not be in line with the interest of the board.
With a contract of zero severance pay in hand, the incumbent manager would expect an aggressive replacement policy and thus
would not exert much first-period effort. In such a case, the board can commit to a positive severance payment, ensuring a low
expected profit for itself after replacement. This would in turn lead to a less aggressive replacement policy, provide more job
security to the incumbent manager, and thus mitigate the period-1 moral hazard problem at the cost of the expenditure from
the severance agreement. Meanwhile, the introduction of a positive severance pay in the contract affects the expected ability
of the second-period manager: the higher the severance pay, the lower the expected ability of the manager who is retained to
save the cost. Therefore, the optimal contract must strike a balance between incentive provision, manager ability selection, and
commitment cost.
Our main result characterizes the optimal replacement policy and shows how it depends on the precision of the signal of the
manager's ability.When t he monitoring technology is noisy,entrenchment is optimal. In such a scenario, the board places higher
priority on motivating the incumbent manager to exert period-1 effort than on maximizing the manager's ability. Designing a
contract to induce an aggressive replacement policy will too often result in the firing of the incumbent of high ability and will
disincentivize the incumbent to exert effort, while saving little on severance pay. As a result, a contract that induces entrenchment
is optimal for the board.
Anti-Entrenchment is optimal when the board's monitoring technology is sufficiently informative. On the one hand, because
the board's monitoring technology is informative, the incumbent manager expects that the turnover rate relies mainly on his
ability rather than the replacement policy. Therefore, a less aggressive replacement policy does not have a significant impact
on motivating period-1 effort. On the other hand, through an aggressive replacement policy the board can (i) avoid the cost of
severance pay when replacement occurs; and (ii) avoid paying the wage to the incumbent manager and undercut the wage in
period 2 to further increase the firm's profit after the incumbent manager exerts his period-1 effort. Thus, anti-entrenchment is
optimal for the board. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to study the interaction between the board's monitoring
technology and managerial turnover, and to show that anti-entrenchment can be part of the optimal contract.
1.1 Related literature
This paper belongs to the literature on the principal–agent model with replacement.2One strand of research views entrenchment
as a potential source of inefficiency that the board aims to mitigate. Consequently,anti-entrenchment cannot be observed. Inderst
and Mueller (2010) solve the optimal contract for the incumbent manager who holds private information on the firm's future
performance and can avoid replacement by concealing bad information.Consequently, the optimal contract is designed to induce
the incumbent to voluntarily step down when evidence suggests low expectedprofit under his management. Similarly, entrench-
ment occurs if the incumbent can make manager-specific investments that create replacement costs for the board (Shleifer &
Vishny, 1989) or if there exist close ties between the board and manager (Hermalin & Weisbach, 1998).
Another strand of research views entrenchment as a feature of the optimal contract (board structure) that helps overcome the
moral hazard problem. Manso (2011) shows that tolerance for early failure (entrenchment) can be part of the optimal incentive
scheme when motivating a manager to pursue more innovative business strategies is important to the board. Casamatta and
Guembel (2010) study the optimal contract for the incumbent manager who is concerned about his reputation. In their model,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT