Managerial response to constitutional constraints on shareholder power

Date01 July 2017
AuthorJinyong Zyung,Brian L. Connelly,Wei Shi
Published date01 July 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2582
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1499–1517 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 26 October 2016 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2582
Received 3 September 2015;Final revision received12 August 2016
MANAGERIAL RESPONSE TO CONSTITUTIONAL
CONSTRAINTS ON SHAREHOLDER POWER
BRIAN L. CONNELLY,1WEI SHI,2,*and JINYONG ZYUNG3
1Raymond J. Harbert College of Business, Auburn University, Auburn, Alabama,
U.S.A.
2Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Indianapolis, Indiana, U.S.A.
3Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of Business, Rice University, Houston, Texas,
U.S.A.
Research summary: We examine whether top managers engage in misconduct, such as illegal
insider trading, illegal stock option backdating, bribery, and nancial manipulation, in response
to the presence, or absence, of governance provisions that impose constitutional constraints
on shareholder power. Within the agency framework, shareholders typically oppose governance
provisions that limit their power because those provisionscould undermine shareholder inuence
and increase agency costs. However, when shareholders support provisions that constrain their
power, managers could respond positively by refraining fromself-interested behavior in the form
of managerial misconduct. Wend this to be especially true in industries where these governance
provisions are particularly relevant to managers and in scenarios where CEOs do not also serve
as board chair.
Managerial summary: In recent years, shareholders have become central to organizations and
the managers who run them. Shareholders and managers establish a rapport with one another,
such that the behavior of one affects the behavior of the other. One of the most consequential
decisions shareholders can make pertains to the reach of their inuence: They can choose to
impose strict governance over rms they own or they can allow for constitutional constraints
that limit shareholder power. When they act in the mutual interest of managers by allowing such
constraints, we nd that managers respondin kind by refraining from bad behavior,such as illegal
stock options backdating, insider trading, and nancial manipulation. This is especially true in
industries and scenarios in which shareholder pressure is most relevant to managers. Copyright
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
The prevailing wisdom of agency theory sug-
gests that shareholders should prevent rms from
adopting corporate governance provisions that pro-
tect top managers against shareholder inuence
(Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell, 2009; Mahoney
Keywords: social exchange theory; agency theory; consti-
tutional limit provisions; managerial misconduct; corpo-
rate governance
*Correspondence to: WeiShi, Kelley School of Business, Indiana
University, 801 West Michigan Street BS 4020, Indianapolis, IN
46202, U.S.A. E-mail: ws7@iu.edu
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
and Mahoney, 1993). Corporate governance pro-
visions are arrangements that top managers pro-
pose that inuence their working relationship with
the rm’s directors and shareholders and the rm’s
vulnerability to takeover (Danielson and Karpoff,
1998). Commonly investigated provisions are poi-
son pills and golden parachutes (Choi, 2004; Davis,
1991), but there is a less glamourous, though
equally important, set of governance provisions
that imposes constitutional constraints on share-
holder power (Bebchuk, 2005). Agency theorists
widely pan any provisions that limit shareholder
inuence as being damaging to rm value (e.g.,
1500 B. L. Connelly, W. Shi, and J. Zyung
Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003; Gompers, Ishii,
and Metrick, 2003; Mahoney, Sundaramurthy, and
Mahoney, 1997), which helps explain why stock
prices often fall when rms adopt such provi-
sions (Datta and Iskandar-Datta, 1996; Mahoney
et al., 1997).
Top managers, however, see things differently.
Governance provisions that limit shareholder inu-
ence are important to top managers because they
provide managers with job security and offer man-
agers the discretion of making decisions that they
believe are in the best interest of the rm and all
its stakeholders (Kacperczyk, 2009). From the man-
agers’ perspective, shareholders are self-interested
when they do not allow rms to have governance
provisions that limit shareholder inuence. That is,
top managers perceive shareholders that preclude
shareholder constraints as being motivated mainly
by a desire to extract value from the rm, even if it
is to the detriment of managers or other stakehold-
ers or comes at the expense of creating long-term
value for the rm (Ambrose and Megginson, 1992).
Conversely, when shareholders afford top managers
the limitations on shareholder inuence managers
desire, they are likely to view shareholders posi-
tively and see them as partners in creating rm value
(David et al., 2010). Therefore, in this study, we
argue that executives may infer shareholder moti-
vation by whether or not shareholders provide them
constitutional limits on shareholder power.
To build understanding about the relationship
between managers and shareholders, it is useful to
consider how research on social exchange theory
(Blau, 1964; Konovsky and Pugh, 1994; Masterson
et al., 2000) can inform what we know of agency
relationships. Scholars have found social exchange
to be foundational to a range of corporate gov-
ernance relationships (Westphal and Zajac, 2013).
For instance, top managers establish exchange rela-
tionships with boards, analysts, and managers at
other rms (Wade, O’Reilly, and Chandratat, 1990;
Westphal and Clement, 2008; Westphal and Zajac,
1997). We extend this logic by examining social
exchange in agency relationships. A key principle
underlying social exchange is norms of reciprocity,
which are dened as “the interest motive of the dyad
partners” (Uhl-Bien and Maslyn, 2003: 514). In
the social exchange between shareholders and man-
agers, top managers infer shareholder motivation
when those managers are afforded, or not afforded,
the constitutional limits to shareholder inuence
that they desire. Establishing such a norm for the
exchange relationship induces reciprocal behavior
on the part of managers (Bosse and Phillips, 2016;
Bosse, Phillips, and Harrison, 2009; Cohen et al.,
2007).
We investigate this possibility in the context of
behavior that is surreptitiously self-interested: man-
agerial misconduct (Cheng and Lo, 2006). Recipro-
cating with overt forms of self-interested behavior
(e.g., extracting personal value through legal and
visible means) could have negative public conse-
quences for managers, but covert self-interested
behavior allows managers to extract personal value
from the rm without necessarily drawing the ire of
shareholders. For example, managers could engage
in illegal insider trading (Cheng and Lo, 2006), ille-
gally backdate stock options (Wiersema and Zhang,
2013), inappropriately book revenue or improperly
value assets (Marcel and Cowen, 2014), or not dis-
close material information to improve the appear-
ance of the company’s performance (Arthaud-Day
et al., 2006). We nd that managers are, in fact,
more likely to engage in managerial misconduct
in the absence of governance provisions that limit
shareholder inuence. Moreover, we introduce
two key boundary conditions to the negative
relationship between these governance provisions
and managerial misconduct, one pertaining to the
industry in which managers operate and another
pertaining to who holds the position of board chair.
Our study offers several potential contributions
to management theory and practice. First, we
challenge the received wisdom about corporate
governance provisions. We develop an understand-
ing of governance provisions from the managers’
perspective that rounds out the shareholders’ per-
spective that dominates the corporate governance
literature (Coates, 2000; Mallette and Fowler,
1992). Whereas prior work has focused on the
economic costs of allowing corporate governance
provisions (Mahoney et al., 1997; Sundaramurthy,
1996), we offer a more nuanced perspective that
accounts for the hidden costs of not allowing
them (Coates, 2000). Second, we develop theory
that is specically oriented toward governance
provisions that constitutionally limit shareholder
power. Prior research has focused mainly on
takeover-contingent governance provisions, but
in the current golden age of shareholder activism
(Goranova and Ryan, 2014) it is increasingly
important to consider governance provisions that
could hinder activism. Third, we take strides toward
integrating research on social exchange theory into
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1499–1517 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT