Local Risk, Local Factors, and Asset Prices

Published date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12465
Date01 February 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2017
Local Risk, Local Factors, and Asset Prices
SELALE TUZEL and MIAO BEN ZHANG
ABSTRACT
Firm location affects firm risk through local factor prices. We find more procycli-
cal factor prices such as wages and real estate prices in areas with more cyclical
economies, namely,high “local beta” areas. While procyclical wages provide a natural
hedge against aggregate shocks and reduce firm risk, procyclical prices of real estate,
which are part of firm assets, increase firm risk. We confirm that firms located in
higher local beta areas have lower industry-adjusted returns and conditional betas,
and show that the effect is stronger among firms with low real estate holdings. A
production-based equilibrium model explains these empirical findings.
MOST WORK IN THE FINANCE literature treats labor and capital markets as per-
fectly competitive and homogeneous at the aggregate level, where wages and
rental rates equalize across locations. In reality, workers face frictions when
moving from place to place (e.g., transaction costs in housing, job search fric-
tions, family coordination issues, etc.). Moreover, a significant part of physical
capital, such as land and structures, is immobile. Production factors that are
subject to such geographical immobility, namely, local factors, account for a
large part of economic output.1Fluctuations in factor prices due to local eco-
nomic conditions can thus have important effects on the firms using them.
In this paper, we show that local factor prices respond to aggregate shocks
differently across localities based on the types of industries that dominate
Both authors are at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California.
We have benefited from conversations with Ken Ahern, Frederico Belo (discussant), Jonathan
Berk, Sandra Black, Daniel Carvalho, Riccardo Colacito, Ed Coulson, Ian Dew-Becker (discus-
sant), Wayne Ferson, Mike Gallmeyer, Mark Grinblatt, Daniel Hirschleifer, Ayse Imrohoroglu,
Chris Jones, Chang-Mo Kang, Leonid Kogan, Erica Li, Debbie Lucas, Hanno Lustig (discussant),
Oguzhan Ozbas, Vincenzo Quadrini, Clemens Sialm, Sheridan Titman, Hakon Tretvoll (discus-
sant), John Wei (discussant), Jiro Yoshido; seminar participants at McGill, UC Irvine, Oregon,
Penn State, CKGSB, UVA McIntire, USC, UT Austin, Jackson Hole Finance Meetings, West-
ern Finance Association Meetings, University of Washington Summer Finance Conference, CAPR
Workshop at BI, USC-UCLA-UCI Finance Day, SFM Conference, and Econometric Society Meet-
ings. Special thanks to Andres Donangelo, Ken Singleton (Editor), and two anonymous referees.
We thank Joseph Engelberg for sharing his data on firm headquarters location changes and Diego
Garcia and Oyvind Norli for providing data on geographic locations of firm operations. The authors
do not have any potential conflicts of interest, as defined in the JF Disclosure Policy.
1The estimates for the output share of labor range from 60% (Cooley and Prescott (1995)) to
75% (Imrohoroglu and Tuzel (2014)). Campbell (1996) uses two-thirds. The output share of land
and structures is roughly 15% (Tuzel (2010)). The two local factors jointly claim more than 75% of
total economic output.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12465
325
326 The Journal of Finance R
those areas. Conceptually,if local factors are immobile across areas, the market
for these factors clears within each area. As a result, local factor prices—for
example, wages and real estate rents—aggregate the shocks to the firms in the
area since all firms tap into the same local labor pool and real estate market. If
the major industries that drive the economy of an area covary highly with the
aggregate economy, local factor prices in that area are likely to be procyclical.
Take, for example, the accommodation industry, which is fairly cyclical. It is the
main industry in three metropolitan areas: Las Vegas, Norwich-New London,
and Atlantic City. Given its significant weight in these economies, these areas
have some of the most cyclical economies in the United States. Thus, during
the 2009 economic downturn, real wages in these three metropolitan areas
declined more than twice the national average. More importantly, the excess
wage decline in these areas relative to the national average occurred not only
in the accommodation sector but also in unrelated sectors such as plastics,
nonmetallic minerals, and transportation equipment manufacturing. These
areas also experienced much larger declines in rents and real estate prices
compared to other metropolitan areas in 2009. Larger fluctuations in input
prices during economic cycles have implications for the risk and returns of
firms located in these areas. We explore these implications in two steps.
To capture the cyclicality of the local economy, we begin by constructing a
measure of local risk, which we refer to as “local beta.” Specifically,we compute
the local beta of a metropolitan statistical area (MSA) as the average of industry
betas weighted by the industry shares in the local market, where an industry’s
beta is the beta of the industry’s output on aggregate GDP. We confirm that the
sensitivity of wage growth (within industry or occupation) to aggregate shocks
is higher in MSAs with high local beta. Similarly, we find more procyclical
house prices, commercial real estate prices, and rents in MSAs with high local
beta, which suggests that demand for real estate is more cyclical in high local
beta areas. These findings support the view that industry composition is an
important driver of the heterogeneous fluctuations in local factor prices.
We next explore the implications of heterogeneous fluctuations in local factor
prices for firm risk by comparing firms in the same industry that are located in
different areas. Intuitively, if all firms in an industry are subject to the same
aggregate productivity shocks, their location will affect their risk and equity
returns only through local production factors. Two competing channels are at
work here. On the one hand, more cyclical wages absorb part of the aggregate
shocks. This provides a natural hedge for firms in high beta areas and lowers
their risk relative to industry peers located in low beta areas. On the other
hand, real estate values also respond more strongly to aggregate shocks in
high beta areas than in low beta areas. Since firm value is derived in part from
the value of its capital, which includes real estate, this mechanism implies
higher equity risk for firms in high beta areas than for firms in low beta areas.
Therefore, for firms that hold real estate, the two channels are expected to have
opposite effects on firm risk.
We find that local beta negatively predicts conditional equity betas and future
equity returns. We also show that this predictability is particularly strong for
Local Risk, Local Factors, and Asset Prices 327
the subsample of firms with few real estate holdings and gets weaker and
insignificant for the subsample of firms with high real estate holdings. These
results are obtained in both panel regressions with time-industry fixed effects
and also in portfolio sorting. Taken together, these findings suggest that both
the labor and the real estate channels are at work, but the labor hedging
channel dominates for the average firm.
To formalize these ideas, we develop a production-based equilibrium model
with local markets. In this model, firms belong to either a low beta industry or
a high beta industry, where the industry beta is determined by the sensitivity
of the industry’s output to aggregate productivity shocks. Local markets have
different compositions of low beta and high beta industries. We also introduce
heterogeneity to the real estate intensity of industries to capture their varying
real estate needs. All firms produce a homogeneous good, receive aggregate
(economy-wide) and firm-level productivity shocks, and use three factors of
production: labor, capital equipment, and land (i.e., immobile capital and real
estate). Labor and land are local factors of production with limited supply,
whereas equipment is not. Firms are ex-ante identical except for their location,
which determines the mix of firms active in their local factor markets, and their
industry affiliation, which determines their exposure to aggregate productivity
shocks and real estate intensity. Wages and land prices clear the local markets
and are determined endogenously, conditional on the industry composition of
the local market. Firms’ investment and hiring decisions are also endogenously
determined in equilibrium.
The calibration of the model generates the main empirical patterns observed
in the data: high beta areas have more procyclical wages and real estate prices
(i.e., higher covariance between aggregate productivity and local factor prices)
than low beta areas. In addition, more procyclical wages act as a natural hedge
against shocks, making the returns of firms in high beta areas less sensitive to
aggregate shocks. Therefore, their expected returns are lower relative to peer
firms in the same industry but located in low beta areas. This is especially true
for firms that belong to industries with low real estate intensity.
To simplify our empirical and theoretical analysis, we make several assump-
tions that merit some discussion. First, we assume that there is no local factor
mobility (labor and land) between local markets. Though land is truly immo-
bile, it is possible for labor to move across markets in response to shocks. Nev-
ertheless, at an annual frequency, job-related mobility is low. Between 2012
and 2013, for instance, only 3.8% of households moved across county lines,
with job-related moves making up roughly one-third of these moves.2Several
2Estimates are from the Census Bureau report, Reason for Moving: 2012 to 2013. The other
two major reasons for moves—family-related (e.g., change in marital status) and housing-related
(e.g., wanted better neighborhood) reasons—each account for one-third of intercounty moves. Chen
and Rosenthal (2008) investigate individual migration decisions using IPUMS (Integrated Public
Use Microdata Series) data. Consistent with the Census statistics, they find that, among movers,
an important reason for moving is the availability of local amenities (e.g., climate, temperature,
nonmetropolitan areas, etc.), which is not directly related to wages. In addition, Kennan and
Walk er (2011) develop an econometric model of optimal migration and estimate moving costs to

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT