Lobbying and Uniform Disclosure Regulation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12118
Published date01 June 2016
Date01 June 2016
AuthorHENRY L. FRIEDMAN,MIRKO S. HEINLE
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12118
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 54 No. 3 June 2016
Printed in U.S.A.
Lobbying and Uniform Disclosure
Regulation
HENRY L. FRIEDMAN
AND MIRKO S. HEINLE
Received 22 January 2014; accepted 4 March 2016
ABSTRACT
This study examines the costs and benefits of uniform accounting regula-
tion in the presence of heterogeneous firms that can lobby the regulator. A
commitment to uniform regulation reduces economic distortions caused by
lobbying by creating a free-rider problem between lobbying firms at the cost
of forcing the same treatment on heterogeneous firms. Resolving this trade-
off, an institutional commitment to uniformity is socially desirable when firms
are sufficiently homogeneous or the costs of lobbying to society are large. We
show that the regulatory intensity for a given firm can be increasing or de-
creasing in the degree of uniformity, even though uniformity always reduces
lobbying. Our analysis sheds light on the determinants of standard-setting in-
stitutions and their effects on corporate governance and lobbying efforts.
JEL codes: D72; G38; L51; M40; M41
Keywords: disclosure; regulation; lobbying
University of California, Los Angeles; University of Pennsylvania.
Accepted by Haresh Sapra. The authors thank an anonymous referee, Franklin Allen,
Stan Baiman, Tony Bernardo, Jeremy Bertomeu, Bruce Carlin, Judson Caskey, Itay Goldstein,
Jack Hughes, Wayne Guay, Bob Holthausen, Rick Lambert, Jack Stecher, and workshop par-
ticipants at the 2012 Junior Accounting Theory Conference, 2013 FARS Midyear Meeting,
Carnegie Mellon University, University of Alberta, and University of Waterloofor helpful com-
ments. Mirko Heinle thanks the Wolpow family for financial support. This paper was previ-
ously circulated as “Lobbying and one-size-fits-all disclosure regulation.” Mistakes are the sole
responsibility of the authors.
863
Copyright C, University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2016
864 H.L.FRIEDMAN AND M.S.HEINLE
1. Introduction
The question of whether to standardize disclosure regulation is a funda-
mental and unanswered problem in accounting research (Dye and Sunder
[2001], Bertomeu and Cheynel [2013]). Individualized regulation (IR) al-
lows for tailoring accounting policies to the characteristics of each regu-
lated firm. Yet, for the most part, accounting rules take a uniform regula-
tion (UR) approach in which, for example, the principles of U.S. GAAP
or IFRS are applied across different firms and industries.1Common argu-
ments in favor of UR are that investors may not understand excessive di-
versity in standards and that uniformity promotes comparability (e.g., Ray
[2012]). We offer an alternative, lesser known benefit of uniformity. Be-
cause firms must lobby over the same set of rules, UR implies that each lob-
byist’s personally costly lobbying effort benefits other lobbyists. Uniformity,
thus, creates a free-rider problem between lobbyists, and greater uniformity
exacerbates this free-riding problem. Hence, uniform rules are less vulner-
able to political influence and serve to reduce equilibrium lobbying efforts
and their social costs.2
In the spirit of Peltzman [1976], Stigler [1971], and recently Bertomeu
and Magee [2011], we model a regulator that is in charge of disclosure
regulation for multiple firms. Each firm faces an agency problem in that an
insider (e.g., a blockholder) can take an action that benefits him/her while
imposing a cost on outsiders (e.g., dispersed investors). As a motivating
example, we focus on asset diversion that is inefficient because the cost to
outsiders exceeds the insider’s benefit (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny [1997]).
Regulation can improve social welfare by reducing insiders’ ability to divert
firm resources for their own gain.
To capture tradeoffs between UR and IR systems, we include a cost to
the regulator of setting different regulations for different firms. A higher
cost of setting different regulations represents a more uniform regulatory
environment. In our model, this cost operationalizes an institutional com-
mitment to common standards, for example, in the form of conceptual
statements or the established preferences of standard-setters. Absent lob-
bying, the regulator chooses the intensity of regulation to minimize diver-
sion, subject to the costs of regulation. While expected diversion decreases
in regulatory intensity, the direct costs of regulation also increase in regu-
latory intensity and, potentially, in regulatory heterogeneity.
1The current FASB chairman, Russell Golden, espoused the benefits of standards in recent
remarks (Golden [2013, p.3]), stating that “standardized financial reporting in the late 19th
and early 20th Centuries helped develop the nation’s steel manufacturing capacity.”
2In this vein, Representative John Dingell (D-MI) said in reference to the FASB: “Their
job is to promulgate accounting standards of high quality that do not favor any particular
industry or interest group and that maintain the credibility of our financial reporting system.
The unparalleled success of the U.S. capital markets is due in no small part to the high quality
of the financial reporting and accounting standards promulgated by FASB” (as quoted in
Beresford [2001, p.78]).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT