Liquidity Supply in the Corporate Bond Market

Published date01 April 2021
Date01 April 2021
AuthorJONATHAN GOLDBERG,YOSHIO NOZAWA
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12991
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXVI, NO. 2 APRIL 2021
Liquidity Supply in the Corporate Bond Market
JONATHAN GOLDBERG and YOSHIO NOZAWA
ABSTRACT
This paper examines dealer inventory capacity, or liquidity supply, as a driver of
liquidity and expected returns in the corporate bond market. We identify shocks to
aggregate liquidity supply using data on corporate bond yields and dealer positions.
Liquidity supply shocks lead to persistent changes in market liquidity,are correlated
with proxies for dealer f‌inancial constraints, and have signif‌icant explanatory power
for cross-sectional and time-series variation in expected returns, beyond standard
risk factors. Our f‌indings point to liquidity supply by f‌inancially constrained inter-
mediaries as a main driver of market liquidity and asset prices.
LIQUIDITY RISK IS PRICED IN the cross section of asset returns: average re-
turns are higher for assets more sensitive to aggregate shocks to market liq-
uidity. The liquidity risk premium has been documented in equities (Amihud
(2002), Pástor and Stambaugh (2003)), corporate bonds (Lin, Wang, and Wu
(2011)), and other asset classes (Sadka (2010)). The mechanisms underlying
the liquidity risk premium and aggregate illiquidity, however, are the subject
of debate.1
Jonathan Goldberg is at the Federal Reserve Board. Yoshio Nozawa (corresponding author,
nozawa@ust.hk) is at the Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST). We thank
Hui Chen; Darrell Duff‌ie; Giovanni Favara; Valentin Haddad; Grace Hu; Yesol Huh; Maureen
O’Hara; Or Shachar; Kairong Xiao; Alex Zhou; participants at the Asian FA, Baltimore Area Fi-
nance, CICF, Erasmus Liquidity, HEC-McGill Winter Finance,ITAM Finance, and SAFE Market
Microstructure conferences; and seminar participants at Penn State, the Federal Reserve Board,
the Securities and Exchange Commission, and the University of California at San Diego. For com-
ments that improved the paper, we are grateful to Stefan Nagel (Editor), two anonymous referees,
an associate editor, and discussants Patrick Augustin, Jack Bao, Frank de Jong, Xiaoxia Lou,
Andreas Rapp, Dragon Tang, and Quan Wen. We thank FINRA for providing transaction data.
FINRA screening was limited to whether there is suff‌icient aggregation such that no particular
dealer is identif‌ied. The authors received, but were not required to incorporate, comments from
Federal Reserve economists. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not nec-
essarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. The authors have no other
material f‌inancial or nonf‌inancial interests related to this research per The Journal of Finance
disclosure policy.
Correspondence: Yoshio Nozawa, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Lee Shau
Kee Business Building, Clearwater Bay, NT,Hong K ong; e-mail: nozawa@ust.hk
1Vayanos and Wang (2013) review the literature.
DOI: 10.1111/jof‌i.12991
© 2020 American Finance Association. This article has been contributed to by US Government
employees and their work is in the public domain in the USA
755
756 The Journal of Finance®
This paper provides evidence connecting market liquidity and expected re-
turns to intermediaries’ inventory-absorption capacity, or liquidity supply. We
propose a new method to identify liquidity supply using the sign restriction
that higher liquidity supply leads to a lower price and a higher quantity of liq-
uidity. We apply this method to the corporate bond market. Our liquidity price
ref‌lects “noise” in corporate bond yields, or deviations from f‌itted issuer-level
yield curves. Our liquidity quantity indicates how dealers use their balance
sheets to provide immediacy. We f‌ind that liquidity supply shocks have persis-
tent effects on noise and dealer positions and signif‌icant explanatory power for
cross-sectional and time-series variation in expected returns.
The corporate bond market is nearly ideal for our purposes. Corporate bonds
are traded in an over-the-counter market in which trading costs are substan-
tial and f‌luctuate signif‌icantly (Bao, Pan, and Wang(2011), Dick-Nielsen, Feld-
hütter, and Lando (2012)). In addition, corporate bonds are a signif‌icant source
of f‌irm f‌inancing. The expected return on corporate bonds has been shown to
have predictive power for f‌inancing f‌lows and real activity (Gilchrist and Za-
krajšek (2012), Ma (2019)). Understanding the determinants of corporate bond
liquidity and returns is thus of foremost importance.
Studying the links between liquidity and asset prices is challenging be-
cause standard liquidity measures are driven not only by dealers’ inventory-
absorption capacity (Grossman and Miller (1988)), but also by investors’ liquid-
ity demand and asymmetric information about the assets traded. To identify
shocks to liquidity supply in the corporate bond market, we focus on dealers’
absorption of demand imbalances for similar bonds. Investor demand to buy
bonds even if they are priced richly (or to sell bonds even if they are priced
inexpensively) generates noise in corporate bond yields. Noise compensates
dealers for absorbing these demand imbalances. We therefore use noise as our
liquidity price.
We measure noise in corporate bond yields using weekly bond-level yield
data from 2002 to 2016. Each week, we f‌it a smooth yield curve for each large
issuer of corporate bonds. Our noise measure is the average, across all bonds
in our sample, of the divergence between a bond’s market yield and the yield
curve of its issuer. Because noise captures deviations from issuer-level yield
curves, it is unaffected by issuers’ credit risk and asymmetries in information
about issuers.
Our focus on noise builds on Fontaine and Garcia (2012) and Hu, Pan, and
Wan g (2013), who study Treasury noise and assume that it is driven by liq-
uidity supply. An increase in noise, however, could ref‌lect a deterioration in
liquidity supply or an increase in investors’ liquidity demand. To address this
concern, we study noise together with the quantity of liquidity provided. To ab-
sorb the demand imbalances that give rise to noise, dealers take long positions
in bonds that investors want to sell and short positions in bonds that investors
want to buy. Thus, as the quantity of liquidity, we use gross positions, the sum
of dealers’ gross long and gross short positions.
Liquidity Supply in the Corporate Bond Market 757
We construct this liquidity quantity using detailed transaction data that al-
low us to identify dealers.2To construct each dealer’s position in each bond,
we cumulate transactions. We def‌ine dealer gross positions as the sum, across
bonds and dealers, of the absolute value of each dealer’s position in each bond.
Next, we estimate a structural vector autoregression (VAR) model of noise
and dealer gross positions. We identify supply shocks as leading contemporane-
ously to opposite-sign changes in price and quantity, whereas demand shocks
lead to same-sign changes in price and quantity.
Our method has several advantages. First, we infer liquidity supply directly
from the price and quantity of corporate bond liquidity,rather than using prox-
ies for f‌irm-wide constraints such as dealer f‌irms’ leverage. Second, our method
also identif‌ies aggregate shocks to investor demand imbalances for similar
bonds, or liquidity demand. We examine whether liquidity demand shocks have
different properties than liquidity supply shocks. Third, our method provides
estimates of the persistence of liquidity supply and demand shocks. A shock
with persistent effects on liquidity is expected to be more important for asset
pricing (Acharya and Pedersen (2005)).
We f‌ind that a positive liquidity supply shock is associated with a decrease
in noise and an increase in positions that are quite persistent. Liquidity sup-
ply shocks are correlated with proxies for dealer inventory capacity such as
dealer capital, corroborating our interpretation of the estimated supply shocks.
Moreover, liquidity supply shocks capture well episodes of intermediary stress,
including key events of the 2007 to 2009 f‌inancial crisis. In contrast, liquidity
demand shocks are associated with transitory changes in noise and positions,
are correlated with lagged corporate bond mutual fund f‌lows and issuance,
and do not follow a consistent pattern around stress events. These differences
in the properties characterizing liquidity supply and demand shocks suggest
that liquidity supply and demand should have different asset pricing implica-
tions.
Using a regression approach similar to that of Fama and MacBeth (1973),
we f‌ind that corporate bonds with returns that are more sensitive to liquidity
supply shocks earn higher expected returns, even when controlling for bond-
level liquidity and other characteristics.3The liquidity supply risk premium
remains signif‌icant when controlling for the sensitivity of each bond to well-
known liquidity measures (Amihud (2002), Pástor and Stambaugh (2003)),
which is consistent with the view that these liquidity measures are driven
by factors beyond just liquidity supply. In contrast, we do not f‌ind evidence for
a liquidity demand risk premium.
2We focus on primary dealers, the main intermediaries in the corporate bond market, and
designated counterparties of the Federal Reserve.We list the primary dealers in Internet Appendix
Section I. The Internet Appendix is available in the online version of the article on The Journal of
Finance website.
3Internet Appendix Section II presents a dynamic equilibrium model that relates liquidity sup-
ply and demand shocks to noise, gross positions, aggregate excess returns, and the cross section of
excess returns.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT