Limited Risk Sharing and International Equity Returns

Date01 April 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12994
Published date01 April 2021
AuthorSHAOJUN ZHANG
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXVI, NO. 2 APRIL 2021
Limited Risk Sharing and International Equity
Returns
SHAOJUN ZHANG*
ABSTRACT
Limited stock market participation can potentially explain the disconnect between in-
ternational asset prices and macro quantities. An incomplete markets model in which
risk sharing for stockholders is high generates highly correlated equity returns and
relatively smooth exchange rates. Risk sharing for nonstockholders is limited because
of their nonparticipation in stock markets and borrowing constraints, reducing the
aggregate consumption correlation and the correlation between aggregate consump-
tion differentials and exchange rates. Financial integration widens the disconnect
by benef‌iting stockholders but hurting nonstockholders. Survey data indicate that
international risk sharing for stockholders is better than that for nonstockholders,
consistent with the predictions.
INTERNATIONAL ASSET PRICES AND QUANTITIES are disconnected. In the
post–Bretton Woods period, quarterly equity returns of the United States have
a correlation of 0.7 with those of the United Kingdom, whereas the corre-
lation between the f‌inancial income of the two countries is 0.14 and that of
nondurable consumption growth is 0.18. This large spread between the cross-
country equity correlation and consumption correlation is known as the inter-
national equity premium puzzle. Similarly, the correlation between the differ-
ences in home and foreign aggregate consumption growth rates (or consump-
tion differentials) and real exchange rate changes is 0.06 between the United
States and United Kingdom, whereas the correlation predicted by theoretical
models is often close to one. This discrepancy is known as the Backus and
*Shaojun Zhang is with The Ohio State University. This paper is based on Chapter 1 of my
doctoral dissertation at NYU Stern School of Business. I thank my advisors Matteo Maggiori,
Thomas Mertens, Stijn van Nieuwerburgh, and Robert Whitelaw for their training and guid-
ance. I acknowledge helpful comments from Rui Alburquerque (discussant); Redouane Elkamhi
(discussant); Aurel Hizmo; Kewei Hou; Christopher Telmer (discussant); Alexi Savov; Lu Zhang;
and seminar participants at CKGSB, Georgetown McDonough, HKU, Hofstra, Minnesota Carl-
son, NYU Stern, OSU Fisher,PSU Smeal, Purdue Krannert, SMU Lee K ongChian, and Tsinghua
PBC seminars, European Financial Association Annual Meeting 2015, American Financial Associ-
ation Annual Meeting 2016, and China International Conference in Finance 2016. I am especially
indebted to the editor Wei Xiong and two anonymous referees for many constructive criticisms
that substantially improved the paper. The author does not have potential conf‌licts of interest to
disclose as def‌ined in The Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy. All remaining errors are my own.
Correspondence: Shaojun Zhang, The Ohio State University.e-mail: zhang.7805@osu.edu.
DOI: 10.1111/jof‌i.12994
© 2020 the American Finance Association
893
894 The Journal of Finance®
Smith (1993) puzzle. Finally, under complete markets and power utility, a high
equity premium and relatively smooth exchange rates imply high international
risk sharing and highly correlated pricing kernels, but the consumption data
indicate otherwise (Brandt, Cochrane, and Santa-Clara (2006)).
A large literature attempts to reconcile international asset prices and quan-
tities under the assumption of complete markets.1Because of modeling con-
venience and data restrictions, the heterogeneity within a country is largely
abstracted away. As a fundamental departure from the literature, I study the
heterogeneity in asset market participation in this paper.
Empirically, using household-level consumption survey data for the United
States and United Kingdom from January 1988 to March 2017, I show that
stockholders achieve better international risk sharing than nonstockholders.
First, stockholders’ cross-country fourth-quarter (Q4-Q4) consumption growth
correlation is as high as 0.56, whereas the aggregate consumption correlation
is only 0.32 and nonstockholders’ consumption correlation is 0.15. Second, the
Backus-Smith correlation, which is the correlation between real exchange rate
changes and consumption differentials, is 0.11 for the aggregate population,
0.15 for stockholders, and as low as 0.22 for nonstockholders. The appar-
ent lack of risk sharing at the aggregate level can therefore be potentially at-
tributed to nonstockholders.
Theoretically, I begin by deriving analytically closed-form results in an in-
complete markets model that features limited risk sharing analytically. I then
turn to a richer quantitative model. Specif‌ically, I f‌irst study a simple analyti-
cal framework with two goods, two countries, and stochastic labor and f‌inancial
income in each country. Agents have power utility that exhibits home bias in
goods and receive a constant fraction of domestic labor income. Stockholders
further receive f‌inancial income. Markets are complete for stockholders, and
nonstockholders live in f‌inancial autarky.
Because of the home bias in goods, following positive home income shocks,
home stockholders’ consumption increases more than foreign stockholders’
consumption to achieve a Pareto optimal allocation. As the demand for foreign
goods increases, foreign goods become more expensive to clear the goods mar-
kets. As such, stockholders’ consumption differentials are perfectly positively
correlated with real exchange rate changes. This is the complete markets role
of real exchange rates.
Second, I analytically study nonstockholders. Following positive home la-
bor income shocks, the income effect leads home nonstockholders’ consump-
tion to increase one-for-one. However, the appreciation of the real exchange
rate makes home nonstockholders’ consumption basket more expensive, damp-
ens the magnitude of their consumption increase, and increases nonstockhold-
ers’ risk sharing. This is the so-called relative price effect (Cole and Obst-
feld (1991)). In contrast, following positive home f‌inancial income shocks, non-
stockholders receive no direct endowment shocks, but the real exchange rate
1Prominent examples include Dumas (1992), Farhi and Gabaix (2008), Verdelhan (2010), and
Pavlova and Rigobon (2007,2012).
Limited Risk Sharing and International Equity Returns 895
appreciation dampens home nonstockholders’ consumption. This adjustment
moves in the opposite direction of the Pareto optimal allocation. In other words,
the relative price effect now reduces risk sharing for nonstockholders and
can lead to a negative cross-country consumption correlation and a negative
Backus-Smith correlation for nonstockholders. In sum, under limited partici-
pation, the tension between complete markets for stockholders and the relative
price effect in incomplete markets for nonstockholders can help reconcile inter-
national asset pricing puzzles.
I next study whether limited participation can lower the aggregate risk shar-
ing enough to resolve the international asset pricing puzzles quantitatively.
The model features an inf‌inite-horizon two-country, two-good economy similar
to the analytical model, but with more realistic asset markets. The economy
has three assets, namely, a home stock, a foreign stock, and a zero net supply
real global bond. The f‌inancial income is the dividend stream of stocks. In this
case, nonstockholders can trade only in the bond market subject to borrow-
ing constraints, whereas stockholders can trade in all asset markets. Markets
are incomplete because of limited stock market participation, borrowing con-
straints, and incomplete spanning of asset markets.
The model generates rich risk-sharing patterns that are consistent with
the data. Risk sharing is high for stockholders but low for nonstockholders
and for the aggregate population. In the aggregate, the model simultane-
ously solves the international equity premium, Backus-Smith, and Brandt-
Cochrane-Santa-Clara puzzles. Stockholders are marginal investors and the
key to generating both high stock return correlations and low exchange rate
volatility. Quantitatively, markets are almost complete for stockholders, as
their Backus-Smith correlation is close to one. Stockholders’ consumption
growth rates are almost perfectly correlated across countries. Equity returns
are also almost perfectly correlated across countries. Because the f‌inancial in-
come is volatile, stockholders’ consumption is also highly volatile. Jointly, the
volatile but highly correlated stochastic discount factors (SDFs) for stockhold-
ers generate high and volatile equity premia and low exchange rate volatility,
thereby solving the Brandt-Cochrane-Santa-Clara puzzle.
Nonstockholders are the source of the apparent lack of aggregate risk shar-
ing. Because of limited participation, real exchange rate variations can provide
only limited risk sharing for nonstockholders through the relative price ef-
fect as in the analytical model. Furthermore, because of their nonparticipation
in equity markets and borrowing constraints, nonstockholders receive limited
risk sharing from asset markets. As a result, nonstockholders’ consumption
growth rates are poorly correlated across countries and their Backus-Smith
correlation is negative.
Comparative statics show that the quantitative success of the model comes
from the tension between complete markets for stockholders and incomplete
markets for nonstockholders. In particular, the income heterogeneity in the
form of f‌inancial income shocks sharpens the tension. First, the access to
international stock markets increases market completeness for stockholders.
Quantitatively, when stock markets are closed, markets are incomplete for all

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT