Leadership Matters

AuthorSusan Summers Raines,Aseem Prakash
DOI10.1177/0095399704272594
Date01 March 2005
Published date01 March 2005
Subject MatterArticles
10.1177/0095399704272594ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY / March 2005Raines, Prakash / LEADERSHIP MATTERS
LEADERSHIP MATTERS
Policy Entrepreneurship in
Corporate Environmental Policy Making
SUSAN SUMMERS RAINES
Kennesaw State University
ASEEM PRAKASH
University of Washington-Seattle
An important feature of the new public management paradigmis the increasing relianceon
voluntary codes rather than coercive mandatory regulation to achievepublic policy objec-
tives. Often, the proponentsof new public management overlook the important contributions
of policy entrepreneurs within regulated firms in popularizing such codes. Focusing on
the environmental policy arena, this article documents that such policy entrepreneurs—
corporate environmentalentrepreneurs—exist in many corporations and significantlyinflu-
ence firms’ adoption of progressive environmental policies. This article uses survey data
from firms in 16 countries to examinethe role of corporate environmental entrepreneursin
the contextof an international voluntary code that seeks to encourage firms to adopt environ-
mentally progressive policies.
Keywords: voluntary environmental programs; ISO 14001; leadership
Governments worldwide face the challenge of meeting citizens’ rising
expectations for the supply of an expanding range of public goods but
without commensurate increases in taxes to finance them (Rosenbaum,
1998). Scholars suggest that such challenges can be met through the adop-
tion of reinventing government and new public management paradigms
(Kettl, 2000; Osborne & Gaebler, 1992). These approaches require a criti-
cal examination of extant regulatory modes and experimentation with new
3
AUTHORS’NOTE: Funding for this project came fromthe National Science Foundation,
Law and Social Sciences division, and Indiana University’s Center for International Busi-
ness, Education, and Research (CIBER).
ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY, Vol. 37 No. 1, March 2005 3-22
DOI: 10.1177/0095399704272594
© 2005 Sage Publications
policy instruments. The need for a new public management approach is
especially true in the environmental policy arena where most regula-
tions reflect the command-and-control mode (Ayres & Braithwaite, 1992;
Fiorino, 2000; Kettl & Armacost, 2002). This tight-fisted style mandates
performance standards and the use of specific technologies. Although
command-and-control policies have significantly contributed to environ-
mental improvements (Cole, 2000), such policies are often difficult to
enforce (Hale, 1998; Scholtz, 1991) and could create sizeable ineffi-
ciencies (static and dynamic) for firms (Esty & Chertow, 1997; Sexton,
Marcus, Easter, & Burkhardt, 1999).
Several new policy instruments have been created to correct the per-
ceiveddrawbacks of command-and-control policies (Prakash & Kollman,
2004). Market-based instruments aim to discourage pollution by using
price signals (OECD, 1989). These policies encourage firms to internalize
the costs of environmental externalities through various price signals.
Mandatory information disclosure policies, such as the Toxics Release
Inventory program, seek to create market and nonmarket pressures on
firms to reduce pollution by requiring a public disclosure of some aspects
of firms’ environmental performance (Arora & Casson, 1996; Hamilton,
1995; Konar & Cohen, 1997). However, both policy types inadequately
deal with regulatory inflation that is reflected in the increasing scope,
number, and complexity of regulations.
Many jurisdictions may also not have the technical and institutional
capacities to design and enforce them. For example, although tradable
permits for air pollution control have been successful in the United States
(such as sulphur dioxide emission markets established under the Clean
Air Act), they have failed in Poland, Germany, and the United Kingdom
(Tietenberg, 2002).
Policy scholars are beginning to focus on another category of policy
instruments: voluntary codes. These could be designed and enforced by
regulators, nonprofit groups, industry associations, and individual firms
either alone or in some sort of mutual partnership (Gibson, 1999; Haufler,
2001). They could vary in their scope focusing on firms around the globe,
in a given region, within a country, or in a given industry. These codes
encourage firms to adopt environmentally progressive policies that are
often beyond the requirements of extant laws. It is important to note, vol-
untary codes seek to reduce enforcement burden on regulatorsand reverse
regulatory inflation without compromising environmental protection. Al-
though voluntary codes are an important component of new public man-
4 ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY / March 2005

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT