Investment Incentives in Open‐Source and Proprietary Two‐Sided Platforms

AuthorRamon Casadesus‐Masanell,Gastón Llanes
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12089
Published date01 June 2015
Date01 June 2015
Investment Incentives in Open-Source
and Proprietary Two-Sided Platforms
RAMON CASADESUS-MASANELL
Harvard Business School,
Strategy Unit Boston, MA 02163
casadesus@gmail.com
GAST ´
ON LLANES
Pontificia Universidad Cat´
olica de Chile,
Santiago, Chile
gaston@llanes.com.ar
We study incentives to invest in platform quality in open-source and proprietary two-sided
platforms. Open platforms have open access, and developers invest to improve the platform.
Proprietary platforms have closed access, and investment is done by the platform owner. We
present five main results. First, open platforms may benefit from limited developer access. Second,
an open platform may lead to higher investment than a proprietary platform. Third, opening one
side of a proprietary platform may lower incentives to invest in platform quality. Fourth, the
structure of access prices of the proprietary platform depends on (i) how changes in the number
of developers affect the incentives to invest in the open platform, and (ii) how investment in the
open platform affects the revenues of the proprietary platform. Finally, a proprietary platform
may benefit from higher investment in the open platform. This result helps to explain why the
owner of a proprietary platform such as Microsoft has chosen to contribute to the development of
Linux.
1. Introduction
Although open-source and proprietary platforms have coexisted since the early days
of the computing industry, competition between these two modes of development has
intensified dramatically following the surge of the Internet in the mid-1990s. Prominent
examples include Linux versus Windows, Open Office versus Microsoft Office, Firefox
versus Safari, Apache versus MS Internet Server, and more recently, Google’s Android
versus Apple’s iOS.
The open-source development model is characterized by two distinctive features:
open access (the freedom to use the software free of charge) and open investment (the
freedom to modify the source code).1Proprietary development, on the other hand, has
We thank two anonymous referees and the Editor for helpful comments that have resulted in a much better
paper. We also thank Jay Pil Choi, Jacques Cr´
emer, Andrei Hagiu, Hanna Hałaburda, Andr´
es Herv´
as-Drane,
Elon Kohlberg, Francisco Ruiz-Aliseda, YaronYehezkel, David Zvilichovsky, and seminar participants at the
Third Annual Searle Center Conferenceon Internet Search and Innovation (Northwestern University), the 39th
Annual Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics (Rome, Italy), the 7th
Bi-annual Conference on The Economics of Intellectural Property,Software and the Internet (Toulouse School
of Economics), and Pontificia Universidad Cat´
olica de Chile. Casadesus-Masanell gratefully acknowledges
financial support from the HBS Division of Research. Llanes gratefully acknowledges financial support from
FONDECYT Initiation to Research Grant No. 11110043.
1. Open access and open investment are complementary but do not always go hand in hand. For example,
MS Explorer is an open-access program, but it does not allow for open investment as the source code is not
made available to users.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 2, Summer 2015, 306–324
Investment Incentives in Two-Sided Platforms 307
closed access and closed investment: the platform owner sets access prices and invests
centrally to improve its quality. The coexistence of these two diametrically opposed
modes of platform governance has sparked a thriving literature on open source ex-
amining why individuals and profit-maximizing firms might choose to contribute to
open-source development (see Lerner and Tirole, 2005; von Krogh and von Hippel,
2006; Fershtman and Gandal, 2011, for recent surveys).
Although insightful and enlightening, theoretical developments on the economics
of open source have fallen short of fully embracing the modeling breakthroughs offered
by the literature on two-sided platforms of the past decade (e.g., Caillaud and Jullien,
2003; Rochet and Tirole, 2003, 2006; Armstrong, 2006; Hagiu, 2006a; Spulber, 2006; Weyl,
2010). Likewise, while the literature on two-sided platforms has studied some aspects of
open platforms, the most distinctive feature of open source (i.e., open investment) has
not been considered.2
In this paper,we bring together these two streams of work to address the following
questions: (i) How are the incentives to invest in platform quality affected by the degree
of platform openness? (ii) What is the relation between access and investment strategies?
and (iii) How are access prices and incentives to invest in platform quality moderated
by competition between open-source and proprietary two-sided platforms?
We set up a model of a platform that brings together users and developers of ap-
plications. Users are heterogeneous in their willingness to pay for access to the platform.
Developers are heterogeneous in that they bear different costs for developing applica-
tions. A proprietary platform chooses how much to invest in platform quality and sets
access prices for each side of the market. An open platform may be accessed for free
and developers may invest in improving its quality.3After users and developers have
accessed the platform, developers compete to sell applications to users. Users prefer
product variety but consider applications as interchangeable. Along with the case of
substitute applications whose marginal value decreases with the number of applications
available, we study the mirror case of complement applications.
Wedivide the analysis into two parts. First, we examine models of proprietary and
open monopoly platforms; that is, we consider incentives to invest in proprietary and
open platforms in isolation from each other and compare equilibrium outcomes. In the
second part, we study a mixed-duopoly model with direct competition between both
types of platforms.
We obtain the following results. First, open platforms may benefit from limited
developer access. The intuition is that the level of investment by developers depends
on the expected profit that these investments generate. If the effect of a change in the
number of applications on developer revenue decreases with investment in platform
quality, a lower number of developers may result in higher investment in the open
platform.
2. To the literature on two-sided platforms, an open platform is one that offers open access, and a pro-
prietary platform is one that has closed access (the platform sets access prices, positive for at least one side).
Thus, this literature is silent about the investment side of platform openness: an open-source platform not
only offers open access but it also allows users and developers to invest in platform quality by modifying the
source code.
3. For concreteness, we focus on developer investment in open platforms and assume away user invest-
ment. Recent empirical evidence suggests that a large share of investments in open source are made by firms
rather than by users. For example, a 2012 report by the Linux Foundation (Corbet et al., 2012) states that 75%
of all Linux kernel development is done by developers who are being paid for their work, and that the top ten
organizations sponsoring Linux development are Red Hat, Intel, Novell, IBM, TexasInstruments, Broadcom,
Nokia, Samsung, Oracle, and Google. Extending the model to include user innovation would only strengthen
our results.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT