Investment Dynamics and Earnings‐Return Properties: A Structural Approach

Published date01 June 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12253
AuthorMATTHIAS BREUER,DAVID WINDISCH
Date01 June 2019
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12253
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 57 No. 3 June 2019
Printed in U.S.A.
Investment Dynamics and
Earnings-Return Properties:
A Structural Approach
MATTHIAS BREUER AND DAVID WINDISCH
Received 18 January 2017; accepted 12 November 2018
ABSTRACT
We propose the standard neoclassical model of investment under uncertainty
with short-run adjustment frictions as a benchmark for earnings-return pat-
terns absent accounting influences. We show that our proposed benchmark
generates a wide range of earnings-return patterns documented in account-
ing research. Notably, our model generates a concave earnings-return rela-
tion, similar to that of Basu [1997], and predicts that the earnings-return
concavity increases with the volatility of firms’ underlying shock processes
and decreases with the level of firms’ investments. We find strong empir-
ical support for these predictions. Overall, our evidence suggests that our
proposed benchmark is useful for understanding the joint dynamics of vari-
ables of interest to accounting research (e.g., earnings, returns, investment,
Columbia University; University of Graz.
Accepted by Rachel Hayes. We gratefully acknowledge helpful code publicly provided
by Dean Corbae and comments and suggestions from two anonymous referees, Ray Ball,
Philip G. Berger, Jeremy Bertomeu, Jonathan Black (discussant), Pietro Bonetti, Jung Ho
Choi, Holger Daske (discussant), Max G¨
odl, Christian Leuz, Brett Lombardi, Valeri Niko-
laev, Ali Cem Randa, Georg Schneider (discussant), Alfred Wagenhofer, Anastasia Za-
kolyukina, and seminar participants at the University of Chicago Booth School of Busi-
ness, Duke University, SKEMA Business School, University of Bath, VHB Conference 2017,
EAA Annual Meeting 2017, AAA Annual Meeting 2017, and the AS-VHB/IAAER Annual
Accounting Conference 2018. An online appendix to this paper can be downloaded at
http://research.chicagobooth.edu/arc/journal-of-accounting-research/online-supplements.
639
CUniversity of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2018
640 M.BREUER AND D.WINDISCH
market-to-book) absent accounting influences, a necessary precondition for
inferring the effects of accounting from these dynamics.
JEL codes: D25; G10; G31; M40; M41
Keywords: dynamic investment; conservatism; earnings-return relation
1. Introduction
A substantial body of accounting research investigates the properties of ac-
counting earnings, such as timeliness and conservatism, by studying the
contemporaneous relation between earnings and returns.1A key challenge
to this literature is to discern the effects of accounting-related factors,
such as accounting rules and managerial reporting discretion, on earnings-
return patterns from the effects of economic fundamentals. Despite recent
progress (e.g., Dutta and Patatoukas [2017], Hemmer and Labro [2018]),
we still lack a basic understanding of how economic fundamentals jointly
determine earnings and returns absent accounting rules and measurement
issues. Without such an understanding of the economic null, however, in-
ferences that can be drawn from empirically observed earnings-return pat-
terns about accounting effects are limited.
In this paper, we propose a simple model of the firm and investigate
its implications for the properties of earnings and returns absent account-
ing rules and measurement issues, to make progress toward an economic
benchmark for earnings-return patterns. In line with economics and fi-
nance literatures, we model the firm as an infinite-horizon dynamic invest-
ment problem under uncertainty with symmetric (convex) capital adjust-
ment costs.2In each period, a risk-neutral manager, acting on behalf of
shareholders, faces a partially persistent shock to the profitability of capi-
tal, the firm’s only fixed production factor, and chooses next period’s capi-
tal stock (through this period’s investment) to maximize the present value
of future cash flows.
Absent a closed-form solution, we numerically solve the model using dy-
namic programming techniques. Equipped with the optimal investment
behavior (policy function) and firm value (value function) for each pos-
sible state, we simulate a time series of earnings, returns, and capital (in-
vestments) in response to a deliberately symmetric exogenous profitability
shock process. The simulated data allow us to investigate the earnings and
return patterns generated by our model.
We show that our proposed model generates a wide range of well-
documented empirical earnings and return patterns. Compared to pre-
vious static valuation models (e.g., Feltham and Ohlson [1995], Ohlson
[1995], Holthausen and Watts [2001]), our model adds two features con-
tributing to its ability to match empirical earnings and return patterns.
1See Kothari [2001] for a survey of the literature.
2See Strebulaev and Whited [2012] for a survey of the literature.
INVESTMENT DYNAMICS AND EARNINGS-RETURN PROPERTIES 641
First, it features real expansion and adaption options (e.g., Burgstahler
and Dichev [1997], Zhang [2000]). These real options introduce notable
nonlinearities in the predicted earnings and return patterns, allowing our
model to match empirical patterns, such as the differential persistence of
profits and losses (e.g., Hayn [1995]) and the nonlinear shape of earnings-
response coefficients (e.g., Freeman and Tse [1992], Wysocki [1999]).
Second, our model features a short-run fixed production factor (due to
time-to-build and convex capital adjustment costs; e.g., Lucas and Prescott
[1971], Hayashi [1982]). This short-run fixed production factor introduces
real dynamics into investment decisions and the earnings process, allowing
our model to match empirical patterns, such as the autocorrelation of in-
vestments (e.g., Cooper and Haltiwanger [2006], Strebulaev and Whited
[2012]) and the earnings-return concavity (e.g., Basu [1997]).
Our model’s ability to generate a concave earnings-return relation is par-
ticularly intriguing, given that it is based on symmetric primitives (e.g.,
symmetric profitability shocks and adjustment costs).3Two channels jointly
generate the prominent earnings-return concavity, even in the absence
of accounting conservatism. First, current-period earnings respond more
strongly to negative than to positive persistent profitability shocks. The in-
tuition behind this is as follows. Suppose a firm experiences a persistent
shock to the profitability of its short-run fixed capital stock (e.g., property,
plant, and equipment) in the current period. To achieve an optimal level
of capital in the future, given the current-period shock, the firm invests or
divests, depending on the sign of the shock. In changing its capital stock,
however, it incurs adjustment costs (e.g., costs associated with production
disruptions and managerial planning) that reduce its current-period earn-
ings. Thus, adjustment costs exacerbate the earnings-decreasing effects of
negative profitability shocks and reduce the earnings-increasing effects of
positive profitability shocks.
Second, and more importantly, future earnings respond more strongly
to positive than to negative persistent profitability shocks. Capital invest-
ments, in response to a persistent positive shock in the current period, al-
low firms to take advantage of their increased demand or productivity in
the future. Hence, the capital expansion in response to a persistent posi-
tive shock increases future earnings (expansion (call) option; e.g., Pindyck
[1988], Wysocki [1999]). By contrast, capital divestments in response to
a persistent negative shock in the current period allow firms to minimize
the impact of their decreased demand or productivity in the future. Thus,
the capital curtailment in response to a persistent negative shock curbs
3For a precise and consistent nomenclature, we refer to an earnings-return relation with
a decreasing slope as a “concave” relation or “earnings-return concavity.” The Basu [1997]
coefficient or asymmetry, for example, represents a special case of a weakly concave earnings-
return relation. By contrast, we refer to an earnings-return relation with an increasing slope
as a “convex” relation or “earnings-return convexity.”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT