Innocents Abroad: The Hazards of International Joint Ventures with Pyramidal Group Firms

AuthorSusan Perkins,Bernard Yeung,Randall Morck
Date01 November 2014
Published date01 November 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.1087
INNOCENTS ABROAD: THE HAZARDS OF
INTERNATIONAL JOINT VENTURES WITH
PYRAMIDAL GROUP FIRMS
SUSAN PERKINS,1* RANDALL MORCK,2and BERNARD YEUNG3
1Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois,
U.S.A.
2Alberta School of Business, University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta,
Canada
3NUS Business School, National University of Singapore, Singapore
We examine international joint ventures in the telecommunications industry in Brazil, where
pyramidal groups are ubiquitous. We explain how corporate governance differences between
pyramidal groups versus widely held freestanding firms can lead to joint venture failures.
Our empirical results show that joint ventures between pyramidal group-member firms and
partners from countries where pyramids are rare have significantly elevated failure rates,
while joint ventures with partners from countries where pyramidal groups are ubiquitous are
more likely to succeed. Further, we provide clinical examples illustrating the mechanisms
driving divergent partnership performance. © 2014 The Authors. Global Strategy Journal
published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Strategic Management Society.
INTRODUCTION
The occurrence of international joint ventures (IJVs)
has increased dramatically over the last few decades,
yet IJVs continue to have high termination rates, at
30 to 70 percent (Franko, 1971; Harrigan, 1988;
Kogut, 1989; Inkpen and Beamish, 1997; Reuer,
2001). The last two decades of research on this topic
have provided insightful explanations for some IJV
terminations. One school of thought argues that joint
venturing is a part of an organizational learning
process (e.g., Kogut, 1989; Hamel, 1991; Inkpen and
Beamish, 1997; Inkpen, 2000; Nakamura, Shaver,
and Yeung, 1996). Joint ventures are dissolved once
their intended purposes are attained (Makino et al.,
2007), particularly when the capabilities of two part-
ners become too similar (Nakamura et al., 1996).
This learning proposition assumes that firms do
not have full information about a host market or
business opportunities. Naturally, then, a second
school of thought argues that some terminations rep-
resent business failures driven by unanticipated fun-
damental differences between partner firms, which
leads to unstable partnership (Franko, 1971;
Harrigan, 1988; Kogut, 1989; Reuer, 2001; Reuer
et al., 2013). Scholars of this conviction have dem-
onstrated that unintended failures result from con-
flicts in knowledge sharing, competitive rivalry
(Kogut, 1989; Park and Russo, 1996), and poor per-
formance (Barkema, Bell, and Pennings, 1996;
Barkema and Vermeulen, 1997; Makino et al.,
2007).
These unintended terminations (Makino et al.,
2007) occur either at formation (e.g., in the selection
of partners) or post formation, when unanticipated
events occur. Some studies (Hambrick et al., 2001;
Reuer and Miller, 1997; Reuer, Zollo, and Singh,
Keywords: corporate governance; international joint ventures;
pyramidal group firms; foreign direct investment
*Correspondence to: Susan Perkins, Kellogg School of Man-
agement, Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan Road,
Evanston, IL 60208, U.S.A. E-mail: s-perkins@kellogg
.northwestern.edu
The copyright line in this article was changed on 26 Novem-
ber after online publication.
Global Strategy Journal
Global Strat. J., 4: 310–330 (2014)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/gsj.1087
© 2014 The Authors. Global Strategy Journal published by
John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Strategic Management Society.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-
NoDerivs License, which permits use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly
cited, the use is non-commercial and no modifications or adaptations are made.
2002; Reuer et al., 2013) focus on formation issues
and reveal that poor partner selection, contract terms,
and board composition significantly contribute to
IJV failures. Other studies (Franko, 1971; Parkhe,
1993a; Ariño and de la Torre, 1998; Reuer et al.,
2002) examine post-formation joint venture partner
interactions, where unanticipated events occur, and
find similar results.
This study enriches the plausible explanations for
unintended IJV failures by combining the partner
choice and post-formation interaction arguments.
We argue that a lack of understanding of the joint
venture partner’s corporate governance and owner-
ship structure subjects a partnering firm to expro-
priation risks and, thus, unsatisfactory performance
unless the governance incentives are aligned and
rights are protected.
Based on data on 96 multinational subsidiaries’
entries into the Brazilian telecommunications indus-
try from 1997 through 2004, our hazard rate regres-
sions show that joint ventures between widely held
freestanding firms and pyramidal group firms are
most at risk for failure, while partnering between
two firms with compatible governance structures is
less hazardous. Our field research includes studies of
joint venture governance agreements and interviews
with senior executives about their experiences and
lessons learned from unanticipated partner behav-
iors. We consolidate the information into four clini-
cal examples to illustrate the causal mechanisms of
international joint venture failure and success
(Parkhe, 1993b). These examples showcase how
widely held freestanding firms unfamiliar with pyra-
midal groups lost control of their joint ventures, suf-
fered from wealth expropriation, and ultimately
exited these underperforming joint ventures. In con-
trast, joint ventures of pyramidal group firms with
other pyramidal group firms have the highest inci-
dence of survival. In these cases, partnering firms
understand each other’s governance and related
incentives and, thus, engage each other on recipro-
cating arrangements that safeguard the joint ven-
ture’s success.
This article proceeds as follows: the next section
discusses differences in corporate governance and
ownership around the world. An ownership form
more commonly found outside of the U.S. is pyra-
midal groups; we discuss how and why pyramidal
group control structures are particularly problematic
for a partnering firm unfamiliar with pyramidal
groups. We then present empirical results linking
joint ventures’ statistical hazard rates in the Brazil-
ian telecommunications industry to foreign partners’
unfamiliarity with pyramidal groups. Next we intro-
duce the case analyses that explore partners’ strate-
gic interactions. The information affirms our
interpretation that a partner unfamiliar with pyrami-
dal group behavior falls victim to a pyramidal part-
ner’s expropriation, leading to unsatisfactory joint
venture experiences. Techniques for expropriating
wealth from foreign joint venture partners are
explained. Countermeasures adopted by joint
venture partners familiar with pyramidal groups are
described, and hazard rate analysis is used to gauge
their effectiveness. We conclude with a discussion
and implications for strategy scholars and foreign
investment managers.
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND
OWNERSHIP AROUND THE WORLD
The international corporate governance literature
describes large cross-country variations in corporate
governance (Granovetter, 1994; La Porta et al.,
1999; Aguilera, Desender, and Kabbach-Castro,
2012; Colpan, Hikino, and Lincoln (2010). Widely
held freestanding firms are common only in the
United States, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands,
and Ireland (Morck, Wolfenzon, and Yeung, 2005).
Elsewhere, controlling shareholders—usually very
wealthy families and occasionally state-owned
enterprises (SOE)—prevail. La Porta et al. (1999)
examine 27 high-income countries and find that,
using a 20 percent definition of control and taking
worldwide averages, only 36 percent of large firms
are widely held. The remaining 54 percent are affili-
ated with pyramidal groups. Of this majority, two-
thirds are controlled by families and one-third by
SOEs. Similarly, regional studies on corporate own-
ership also find a high incidence of pyramidal
ownership—Morck, Stangeland, and Yeung (2000)
report a high incidence of pyramidal group control in
large Canadian firms; in nine East Asian countries,
Claessens, Djankov, and Lang (2000) find a control-
ling shareholder in more than 67 percent of the firms;
Faccio and Lang (2002) find that 37 percent of
Western European firms are widely held firms and 44
percent are family controlled; and Pedersen and
Thomsen (1997) find similar results in 12 European
countries. Fogel (2006) confirms the preponderance
of wealthy family control over the 10 largest busi-
ness entities (groups or freestanding firms) in most
countries. In Brazil, Portugal, Mexico, Argentina,
Innocents Abroad: The Hazards of International Joint Ventures 311
© 2014 The Authors. Global Strategy Journal published by
John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Strategic Management Society
Global Strat. J., 4: 310–330 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/gsj.1087

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT