Information Acquisition and Innovation under Competitive Pressure

AuthorAndrei Barbos
Published date01 June 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12096
Date01 June 2015
Information Acquisition and Innovation under
Competitive Pressure
ANDREI BARBOS
Department of Economics
University of South Florida
4202 East Fowler Avenue, CMC 206, Tampa, FL 33620-5500
andreibarbos@gmail.com
This paper studies information acquisition under competitive pressure and proposes a model to
examine the relationship between product market competition and the level of innovative activity
in an industry. Our paper offers theoretical support for recent empirical results that point to
an inverted-U shape relationship between competition and innovation. The model presents an
optimal timing decision problem where a firm endowed with an idea trades the benefits of waiting
for additional information on whether this idea can be converted into a successful project against
the cost of delaying innovation: a given firm’s profit following innovation is decreasing in the
number of firms that invested at earlier dates. By recognizing that a firm can intensify its
innovative activity on two dimensions, a risk dimension and a quantitative dimension, we show
that firms solve this trade-off precisely so as to generate the inverted-U shape relationship. The
dynamic setup of our model offers insights not just in the cross-section on the relationship between
competition and innovation, but also intertemporally on the optimal timing of innovation at firm
level.
1. Introduction
This paper studies information acquisition under competitive pressure and employs
the resulting model to investigate the relationship between the degree of competition
in an industry and the intensity of innovative activity. The clear policy implications of
the nature of this relationship generated a large body of literature that investigated it.
Beginning with the seminal work of Schumpeter (1943), the objective of these studies has
been to determine whether there is an optimal market structure that resultsin the highest
rate of technological advance. In particular, the literature tried to reconcile the intuitive
appeal of Schumpeter’s assertion that only large firms possessing a significant amount of
monopoly power have the resources and incentive to engage in risky innovative activity,
with a substantial amount of empirical literature that did not confirm it. More recent
empirical papers, such as Aghion et al. (2005) suggest an inverted-U shape relationship
between product market competition and innovation.1According to these studies, for
low levels of competition, an increase in competition induces more innovation, whereas
for higher values of competition, as competition increases, firms become less innovative.
Our paper adopts a microeconomic approach and constructs a model that studies
the innovation process at firm level by following a new project through its stages of
I have benefited from helpful feedback from Alessandro Pavan and Marciano Siniscalchi. I also thank com-
ments and suggestions from the editor,two referees, Andrew Daughety, Eddie Dekel, Silvana Krasteva, Sorin
Maruster, Asher Wolinsky,and from audiences at USF, FSU, IIOC 2010, and ESWC 2010. All errors are mine.
1. Scherer (1967) is the first empirical paper to uncover this shape. See also Scott (1984) and Caves and
Barton (1990).
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 2, Summer 2015, 325–347
326 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
development. The firms in our dynamic model become sequentially aware of an inven-
tion and decide on whether and when to undertake a costly investment in innovation.
In making this decision, firms face a trade-off between seeking a first-mover advantage
and waiting to acquire more information. Our study brings three main contributions to
the literature. First, we identify the trade-off between information acquisition and com-
petitive pressure as sufficient to generate the empirically observed inverted-U shape
relationship. Second, we propose a new dimension, the risk dimension, on which a firm
can intensify its innovative activity. Due to the strong intuitive nature of Schumpeter’s
assertion, the vast majority of theoretical models investigating the relationship between
competition and innovation obtained a negative relationship. By disentangling the level
of innovative activity along two dimensions, the quantitative and risk dimensions, we
succeed in offering an explanation for the positive segment of the relationship.2Finally,
the dynamic setup of our model offers insights not just in the cross-section on the rela-
tionship between competition and innovation, but also intertemporally on the optimal
timing of innovation at firm level. Thus, although our model aims at explaining an
empirical fact of public policy relevance, from a managerial viewpoint, its results elicit
how forward-looking profit-maximizing firms should adjust their innovative activity in
response to increased competitive pressure.
The model has a set of firms who, through their applied research activity, discover
an invention or an idea that could generate future revenues for its investors, provided
that it is a success from both a technological and a business standpoint. Once a firm is
aware of the idea, it has the option to invest in the innovation of that project at any time.
Innovation means the development of a marketable product; it is the stage in the R&D
process where the first substantial financial commitment to the project is made and large
R&D labs spend most of their resources on innovation. For instance, of the $208.3 billion
spent on industrial R&D in the United States in 2004, $155.1 billion (or 74.5% ) were
spent for development.3
When firms first learn of an idea, their knowledge about its feasibility is scarce, so
investment is risky.As time passes, a firm in our model acquires new information and is
able to better assess its chances of success. This additional information may lead a firm
to decide not to invest in the project. This makes waiting beneficial as it can potentially
aid avoiding the financial losses associated with the development of an unsuccessful
product. In real world, the information employed to screen out the less promising
project can take a variety of forms. First, this information can be technological, in the
form of test results, or knowledge about the technological trend for complementary
products. For instance, the potential developers of a hybrid or electric car may have had
an incentive to wait to see if more efficient batteries could be produced. Second, this new
information could also be commercial in the form of marketing research. For instance,
the same car manufacturer may have waited to investigate whether and how many
consumers are willing to compromise and accept the limitations of these new products.
Third, the information may come in the form of knowledge about the overall economic
2. Also, our model can be seen as a study of product innovation where new products are introduced in
the market. This differs from most of the theoretical literature on innovation, including Aghion et al. (2005),
which focuses on process innovations where existing products are produced at a lower average cost.
3. Source: National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics. 2008. Research and Devel-
opment in Industry: 2004.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT