Income Hedging, Dynamic Style Preferences, and Return Predictability

AuthorALOK KUMAR,STEFANOS DELIKOURAS,JAWAD M. ADDOUM,GEORGE M. KORNIOTIS
Date01 August 2019
Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12775
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2019
Income Hedging, Dynamic Style Preferences, and
Return Predictability
JAWAD M. ADDOUM, STEFANOS DELIKOURAS, GEORGE M. KORNIOTIS,
and ALOK KUMAR
ABSTRACT
We propose a theoretical measure of income hedging demand and show that it affects
asset prices. We focus on the value factor and first demonstrate that our demand esti-
mates are correlated with the actual demands of retail and mutual fund investors. We
then show that the aggregate high-minus-low (HML) demand predicts HML returns.
Exploiting the state-level variation in income risk, we demonstrate that state-level
hedging demands predict state-level HML returns. A long-short portfolio that exploits
this hedging-induced predictability earns an annualized risk-adjusted return of 6%.
INCOME RISK IS A FUNDAMENTAL source of uncertainty that households face, and
hence it should affect their financial decisions. Several recent studies demon-
strate that income risk influences the portfolio decisions of U.S. and Euro-
pean households. For example, Angerer and Lam (2009) demonstrate that U.S.
households with higher permanent income risk invest less in risky assets.
Betermier et al. (2012) show that the financial decisions of Swedish households
are sensitive to wage volatility.
A related literature provides household-level evidence that portfolio deci-
sions are affected by income hedging considerations. Bonaparte, Korniotis, and
Kumar (2014) find evidence of income hedging in the decisions of Dutch and
U.S. households. They show that households whose income growth is highly
correlated with market returns participate less in the market and allocate
less of their wealth to risky assets. Using Swedish data, Betermier, Calvet,
and Sodini (2017) argue that the tilt of some investors toward value versus
growth stocks is motivated by income hedging concerns. They show that income
Jawad M. Addoum is with S.C. Johnson College of Business, Cornell University. Stefanos De-
likouras, George M. Korniotis, and Alok Kumar are with University of Miami Business School. We
thank three anonymous referees; an anonymous Associate Editor; Sandro Andrade; Tim Burch;
Sean Campbell; Vidhi Chhaochharia; Jason Delaney; Andrew Karolyi; David Ng; Tarun Ramado-
rai; Kenneth Singleton (Editor); Luis Viceira; Deniz Yavuz; and seminar participants at Cornell
University,the Federal Reserve Board in Washington DC, Florida International University,Goethe
University Frankfurt, University of Mannheim, University of Miami, University of Warwick, the
2016 EFA Annual Meeting, NTA 106th Annual Conference on Taxation, and 2016 SFS Finance
Cavalcade for helpful comments and valuable suggestions. We are responsible for all remaining
errors and omissions. The authors have no conflicts of interest as identified by the Journal of
Finance Disclosure Policy.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12775
2055
2056 The Journal of Finance R
hedging considerations are strongest for those households with high human
capital and high exposure to aggregate risk.1Korniotis and Kumar (2011)
further demonstrate that certain types of financial assets facilitate income
smoothing and improve risk sharing across U.S. states.
Motivated by the household-level evidence on income hedging, in this pa-
per, we examine its potential asset pricing implications. In particular, we in-
vestigate the potential link between the aggregate income hedging behavior
of U.S. households and the predictability in stock returns. Our primary con-
jecture is that the demand for financial assets that facilitate income hedging
varies as their hedging potential changes over time. If such hedging-induced de-
mand shifts are systematic, they could affect prices. This conjecture is partially
motivated by dynamic portfolio choice models, which demonstrate that when
investment opportunities are time-varying, investors should rebalance their
portfolios as they learn about future investment opportunities (e.g., Campbell
and Viceira (1999), Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004), and Jurek and Viceira
(2011)).
We connect this basic prediction of dynamic portfolio choice models with the
literature on style investing, which shows that investors systematically move
in and out of certain investment styles (e.g., Barberis and Shleifer (2003),
Kumar (2009), and Wahaland Yavuz (2013)). We argue that style shifts between
value and growth stocks might be motivated in part by the time-variation in
income hedging opportunities. Such systematic demand shifts could generate
predictable variation in the returns of value and growth portfolios.
We formalize this economic insight in a model that combines the noise trader
specification of De Long et al. (1990), the Bayesian framework of Barberis
(2000), and the income hedging model of Viceira (2001). In the model, there
are two groups of investors. The first group comprises workers, who receive
stochastic income and are concerned about income risk. The second group is
the sophisticated investors, who are risk neutral and face transaction costs.
We solve the model analytically, and obtain explicit solutions for the optimal
portfolios of workers and sophisticated investors. Similar to Viceira (2001),
asset demands by workers include an income hedging term, which depends on
the covariances between asset returns and income, scaled by the covariance
matrix of asset returns. This covariance-based term is our proposed measure
of income hedging demand (IHD).
When the conditional covariance between income and an asset decreases,
the income hedging potential of this asset increases and the IHD measure
increases. Workers then demand more of the asset, creating price pressure,
which in our model cannot be fully absorbed by the sophisticated investors
due to transaction costs. This price pressure today generates lower returns in
the future. Overall, the key theoretical prediction is that there is a neg ati ve
relation between our IHD measure and future asset returns.
1Other papers related to income hedging include Heaton and Lucas (2000), Viceira (2001), and
Vissing-Jorgensen (2002).
Income Hedging, Dynamic Style Preferences, and Return Predictability 2057
To test our predictability hypothesis, we focus on the value factor or the
high-minus-low (HML) style portfolio. We focus on the HML factor because ex-
isting literature suggests that income risk affects the choice between value and
growth stocks. For example, studies using aggregate data find that the value
premium is related to income hedging. In particular, Koijen, Lustig, and
Nieuwerburgh (2017) show that value stocks are especially risky because their
cash flows are low during deep recessions, that is, during periods when aggre-
gate income growth is very negative. Thus, investors could hedge against this
risk by investing in growth stocks.
Betermier, Calvet, and Sodini (2017) provide direct evidence of income hedg-
ing using household-level data. They find that households with high income
risk or high human capital and households employed in highly cyclical sectors
avoid value stocks and prefer growth stocks. Cronqvist, Siegel, and Yu (2015)
also find that value versus growth investing is one of the most predominant
investment styles. Further, they show that households with higher human cap-
ital (i.e., high labor income and high education) tend to prefer growth stocks.
Moreover,investors with more procyclical income (i.e., high correlation between
labor income growth and GDP growth) also tend to prefer growth stocks.
We also focus on the HML portfolio because it satisfies the necessary con-
ditions required to generate predictability in returns. First, value and growth
investment styles have been popular as far back as the 1930s (e.g., Graham and
Dodd (1934)). Further, the average investor can easily gain exposure to value
and growth portfolios (Wahal and Yavuz (2013)). Jurek and Viceira (2011) re-
port that in the universe of mutual funds in the Center for Research in Security
Prices (CRSP) database, about 78% of funds can be categorized as either value
or growth funds. Second, the income hedging potential of the HML portfolio
varies significantly over time, which generates time-varying demand shifts
that can potentially influence stock prices.
Since hedging-induced investments cannot be directly observed, we estimate
the IHD using the relation predicted by our model. Because we want to examine
the aggregate asset pricing implications of income hedging, we construct the
IHD using aggregate U.S. and state-level income data. Specifically, we adopt a
conditional estimation approach where we compute variances and covariances
using a 10-year rolling window. Using these conditional moment estimates we
compute IHD at both the U.S. state level and the national level. As shown in
Figure 1, the IHD estimates exhibit substantial variation in the cross section
and over time. For instance, in every period some U.S. states have negative
while others have positive IHD estimates.
Before using our IHD measure to predict asset returns, we investigate
whether these theoretical demand estimates are related to actual investor
demands for value and growth stocks. We perform two validation tests. In the
first test, we compute the relative portfolio weights in value and growth stocks
based on the actual stock holdings of a sample of retail investors. We find that
the correlation between the actual relative weight and our IHD measure is
positive and statistically significant.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT