Incentives, Capital Budgeting, and Organizational Structure

Published date01 December 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12033
Date01 December 2013
Incentives, Capital Budgeting, and Organizational
Structure
ADOLFO DE MOTTA
Desautels Faculty of Management
McGill University
Montreal, Quebec, Canada, H3A 1G5
adolfo.demotta@mcgill.ca
JAIME ORTEGA
Department of Business Administration
Universidad Carlos III de Madrid
28903, Getafe (Madrid), Spain
jaime.ortega@uc3m.es
Divisional managers compete for financial resources in what is often referred to as an internal
capital market. They also have a common interest in maximizing corporate profits, as this
determines the resources available to the firm as a whole. Both goals are powerful motivators
but can at times conflict: while the amount of resources available to the firm depends on corporate
performance, divisional funding depends upon the division’s performance relative to the rest. We
propose a model in which organizational form is endogenous, divisions compete for corporate
resources, and managers have implicit incentives. We show that organizational design can help
companies influence their divisional managers’ potentially conflicting goals. Our analysis relates
the firm’s organizational structureto the source of incentives (external vs. internal), the nature of
the incentives (competition vs. cooperation), the level of corporate diversification, the development
of the capital market, and to industry and firm characteristics.
1. Introduction
In large corporations one of headquarters’ main functions, and arguably the most impor-
tant one, is the allocation of resources across differentlines of business—this determines
how corporations grow and evolve over time. Divisional managers compete for re-
sources in what is often referred to as an internal capital market. Yet, managers have
also a common interest in increasing corporate profits so that the firm attains more re-
sources, which can then be channeled to all divisions. Both types of incentives motivate
managers but can sometimes conflict. For example, actively participating in a project
launched by another division can increase corporate profits but may not help one’s po-
sition when competing for internal resources. In fact, engaging in less profitable projects
might be more rewarding from the divisional managers’ perspective if they can more
convincingly claim credit for them. In order to prevent divisions’ particular interests
from harming firm performance, companies need to find ways to channel those interests
We thank the editor, coeditor, and two referees for very helpful comments and suggestions. Adolfo de Motta
gratefully acknowledges funding from the FQRSC program. Jaime Ortega gratefully acknowledges funding
from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation (research grants ECO2009-08278 and ECO2012-33308)
and the Community of Madrid (research grant S2007/HUM-0413).
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 4, Winter 2013, 810–831
Capital Budgeting and Organizational Structure 811
toward corporate goals. This article shows how an appropriate organizational structure
can help.
Weuse a career concerns model (Holmstr ¨
om, 1982) to formalize the dynamic nature
of incentives: investors and corporate headquarters draw inferences from current profits
about the productivities of differentlines of business, which are ex ante unknown, and use
those inferences for capital budgeting. Divisional managers have incentives to influence
this learning process, and hence future investments, by taking costly unobserved actions
that increase profits. In this set up, we study how a multi-product firm fares under
different organizational structures, paying special attention to the most common types
of structure, the so-called unitary and multidivisional forms (U-form and M-form). In
a U-form organization, each divisional manager has responsibilities over all products
or business lines, but her responsibilities are limited to a single function, for example,
marketing or production; whereas in an M-form each divisional manager is responsible
for a single product and controls all functions related to that particular product.
Irrespective of the organizational form, in the model, headquarters are free to
decide how funds are allocated across products, but must allocate functional resources
in fixed proportions. The fixed proportions assumption is made for simplicity, the main
idea being that there is a greater degree of substitutability across products than across
functions. That is, firms can generally do without a particular line of business if it is not
profitable but need to invest in all functional areas for the lines of business in which
they operate.1Empirically,large corporations tend to operate in more than one SIC code,
and, more importantly, they are often involved in acquisitions, alliances, and divestitures
(e.g., 86 Fortune-100 firms were involved in a total of 9,276 acquisitions, alliances, and
divestitures during the 1990s—see Villalonga and McGahan, 2005), which suggests that
reallocations of resources indeed occur primarily across products.
To understand the logic of the model, consider first a U-form organization. Given
that each division manages a number of functions across all products, the internal
allocation of resources by corporate headquarters does not induce competition among
divisional managers.2In these organizations, a division’s funding is mainly determined
by the total amount of funds available for the whole corporation, which depends on
how investors perceive the firm. Divisional managers have incentives to improve this
perception by increasing current profits as this translates into more financing for the
corporation and hence, for their respective divisions.
Incentives work differently in an M-form organization. Because each division is
responsible for one product or line of business, a division’s funding depends not only on
the total funds available for the whole corporation, but also on the share of those funds
that are channeled to each product by corporate headquarters. In this case divisional
managers have incentives to improve both the external perception of the corporation (to
increase total funding) and the internal perception of their divisions (to increase their
own division’s internal funding). More importantly, these two objectives can conflict:
while internal competition for resources provides divisional managers with incentives
1. Even if a firm decides to outsource some functional processes, outsourcing is limited by informational
and hold-up problems (e.g., Grossman and Hart, 1986) and these processes still need to be funded (i.e.,
outsourced goods and services have to be paid for and firms must keep a minimum amount of in-house
resources to ensure proper coordination with suppliers).
2. In general, as long as headquarters’ reallocation of resources across products or business lines is more
important than across functions, a U-form organization will tend to induce less internal competition for
corporate resources than an M-form organization.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT