Idiosyncratic Volatility and Firm‐Specific News: Beyond Limited Arbitrage

Published date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12135
Date01 December 2016
AuthorR. Jared DeLisle,Adam R. Smedema,Nathan Mauck
Idiosyncratic Volatility and Firm-Specific
News: Beyond Limited Arbitrage
R. Jared DeLisle, Nathan Mauck, and Adam R. Smedema
Weexamine the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and returns aroundnews announcements.
Mispricing is most likely to occur during news announcements. If idiosyncraticvolatility generates
a limit to arbitrage, then the negative relation between returns and news volatility should be
stronger than the relation to nonnews volatility. Instead, we find nonnews volatility has a robust
negative relation to returns and lackskey features expected if volatility were a reflection of limits
to arbitrage.Pricing of nonnews volatility is related to lottery-like features of a stock’sreturn. Our
results suggest that volatility has a price effect beyond a limit to arbitrage.
Since classical asset pricing theory predicts either no relation or an intuitive positive relation
(Levy, 1978; Merton, 1987) between returns and idiosyncratic risk, Ang et al.’s (2006, 2009)
finding of a negative relation between average monthly returns and short-term idiosyncratic
volatility presents a substantial puzzle.1While idiosyncratic volatility is typically assumed to
capture firm-specif ic news announcements, little effort has been spent relating the pricing of
idiosyncratic volatility to actual firm-specific news announcements.2This omission is particularly
stark since one of the most promising explanations for the negative price relation, the limited
arbitrage explanation from Stambaugh, Yu, and Yuan (2015), has an important role for firm-
specific news.3
Since volatility limits demand from arbitrageurs (Barberis and Thaler, 2003; Pontiff, 2006),
stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility are potentially mispriced and the relation between
We thank the editor (Marc Lipson), an anonymous referee, Ajay Bhootra, Arthur Cox, Richard Followill, and seminar
participants at the University of Northern Iowa, the 2016 Southwest FinanceAssociation meeting, and the 2016 Eastern
Finance Association meeting.
R. Jared DeLisle is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Economics and Finance at Utah State University
in Logan, UT. Nathan Mauck is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Finance at the Henry W. Bloch School of
Management at the Universityof Missouri – Kansas City in Kansas City,MO. Adam R. Smedema is an Assistant Professor
and the Tim Williams Junior Faculty Fellow in the Department of Finance at the University of Northern Iowa in Cedar
Falls, IA.
1We use the term “short-term idiosyncratic volatility” to denote the measure we use throughout this study. Following
Ang et al. (2006), we use returns at a monthly granularity, but estimate volatility over the previous month using daily
returns. We call this “short-term” to stress that we only consider this one particular methodology and to distinguish this
method from the other common measure of idiosyncratic volatility that uses a long time series of monthly returns to
forecast future monthly volatilityfrom generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models (Guo, Kassa, and
Ferguson, 2014; Chicherna, Ferguson,and Kassa, 2015). Results from previous studies, such as Fu (2009) and Peterson
and Smedema (2011), suggest that these are two different phenomena despite their similar construction.
2The notable exception to this is Bali, Scherbina, and Tang (2011), who look at a two-year period of corporate press
releases and find the presence of these releases are positively related to increases in idiosyncratic volatility.Their research,
like Boehme, Danielsen, and Sorescu (2006) and Boehme, Danielsen, Kumar, and Sorescu (2009), primarily focuses on
using Miller’s(1977) difference of opinion to explain the negative price of idiosyncratic volatility, which is outside the
scope of our research.
3While this explanation is most closely attributable to Stambaugh et al. (2015), one could drawsimilar conclusions from
the results of many other studies, such as Brav, Heaton, and Li (2010), Duan, Hu, and McLean (2010), and Bhootra and
Hur (2015), who link the pricing of other overvaluation anomalies to idiosyncratic volatility.
Financial Management Winter 2016 pages 923 – 951
924 Financial Management rWinter 2016
idiosyncratic volatility and subsequent returns is due to the correction of the mispricing. This
explanation leads to four expected features of the pricing of idiosyncratic volatility.4First, since
short selling is more constrained than stock purchases, high-volatility stocks are, on average,
overvalued and will have negative alphas as the stocks’ prices fall to correct the overvaluation.
In addition, stocks with low idiosyncratic volatility are fairly priced and should have alphas of
approximately zero since their low volatility does not limit arbitrageurs from correcting mis-
pricing. Moreover, among potentially overvalued stocks (e.g., stocks with high short interest),
the negative relation between volatility and subsequent returns is particularly strong. Finally,
among potentially undervalued stocks (e.g., stocks with high book-to-market ratios), the relation
between volatility and subsequent returns is potentially positive as the stock’s price must rise to
correct the undervaluation. Since these four features are well established in the literature, the
limited arbitrage explanation seems to provide a simple and plausible explanationfor the negative
volatility and returns relation.
In this study, we evaluate the limited arbitrage explanation of the pricing of idiosyncratic
volatility by examining actual firm-specific news announcements. The pricing of idiosyncratic
volatility,by this explanation, should be related to fir m-specific news. While limited arbitrage is a
necessary condition for mispricing, it is not sufficient. Some impetus must create a divergence of
prices from fundamental values that arbitrageurs fail to expeditiously correct. Since firm-specific
news moves prices (Ryan and Taffler, 2004; Bali, Scherbina, and Tang, 2011), material firm
announcements should increase the likelihood of short-term mispricing (Ball and Brown, 1968;
Pritamani and Singal, 2001). Thus, the four features associate with the pricing of idiosyncratic
volatility should be strongest when volatility is contemporaneous with news announcements.
Our examination of firm-specif ic news announcements suggests that the limited arbitrage ex-
planation cannot fully explain the pricing of idiosyncratic volatility. In this study,our f irm-specific
news data are the announcement or declaration dates for: 1) share repurchases, 2) seasoned equity
offerings (SEOs), 3) debt issuances, 4) as an merger and acquisition (M&A) target, 5) an M&A
acquirer, 6) an insider trade, 7) an analyst recommendation, 8) earnings, 9) dividends, or 10)
a stock split. The extant literature indicates that all of these events impact a firm’s stock price.
We decompose short-term idiosyncratic volatility into “news volatility” and “nonnews volatil-
ity.” News volatility is the idiosyncratic volatility related to firm-specif ic news announcements.
Nonnews volatility is the idiosyncratic volatility unrelated to news announcements. The pricing
of news volatility supports the limited arbitrage explanation as it demonstrates the four features
identified above, but its pricing is weak and not robust.
Contrary to the limited arbitrage explanation, we find that idiosyncratic volatility on nonnews
days is more strongly related to future returns than the volatility on newsdays. Further, the pricing
of nonnews volatility does not demonstrate all four features expected by the limited arbitrage
explanation. The negative relation between returns and nonnews volatility when estimated with
zero-cost portfolios that are short low-volatility stocks and long high-volatility stocks is sig-
nificantly negative, both statistically and economically. The monthly average alpha of our base
model is –66 bp (t-statistic of 4.08). However, low nonnewsvolatility por tfolios havesignif icantly
positive alphas (12 bp per month, t-statistic of 2.25). Furthermore, while the price of nonnews
volatility increases somewhat across stocks with different levels of overvaluation, the increase is
certainly not monotonic and the negativerelation is not pooled in only the most overvalued stocks.
Finally, when forming a portfolio with the least undervalued stocks, nonnews volatility-sorted
4Features one, three, and four are explicitlyenumerated by Stambaugh et al. (2015). We believe the second feature is also
consistent with the limited arbitrage explanation.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT