Idiosyncratic Cash Flows and Systematic Risk

Published date01 February 2016
AuthorYURI TSERLUKEVICH,ILONA BABENKO,OLIVER BOGUTH
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12280
Date01 February 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2016
Idiosyncratic Cash Flows and Systematic Risk
ILONA BABENKO, OLIVER BOGUTH, and YURI TSERLUKEVICH
ABSTRACT
We show that unpriced cash flow shocks contain information about future priced risk.
A positive idiosyncratic shock decreases the sensitivity of firm value to priced risk
factors and simultaneously increases firm size and idiosyncratic risk. A simple model
can therefore explain book-to-market and size anomalies, as well as the negative
relation between idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns. Empirically, we find that
anomalies are more pronounced for firms with high idiosyncratic cash flow volatility.
More generally, our results imply that any economic variable correlated with the
history of idiosyncratic shocks can help to explain expected stock returns.
IT IS WELL ESTABLISHED that, under standard asset pricing assumptions, only
systematic risk is priced. In this paper, we argue that unpriced idiosyncratic
cash flow shocks can also be important for asset prices as they contain valuable
conditioning information in a dynamic asset pricing framework. In particular,
we show that the conditional beta with respect to any priced source of risk
depends directly on the history of firm-specific shocks. We use this insight to
provide risk-based explanations for several anomalies in the cross-section of
equity returns, including the widely documented value and size effects, the
negative relation between idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns, and the
underperformance following investment and equity issuance.1
To understand why firm-specific shocks are useful as conditioning informa-
tion, consider a firm with two divisions. Suppose the profit of the first division
depends exclusively on idiosyncratic profitability shocks and the profit of the
All authors are with the W.P.Carey School of Business at Arizona State University. The authors
thank Ken Singleton (the Editor) and two anonymous referees as well as Jonathan Berk; Sreed-
har Bharath; Scott Cederburg; Darrell Duffie; Laurent Fr´
esard; Robert Hodrick; Søren Hvidkjær;
Rajnish Mehra; Kristian Miltersen; Dimitris Papanikolaou; Lasse Pedersen; Mark Rubinstein;
Toni Whited; and seminar participants at Arizona State University, Copenhagen Business School,
Erasmus University, New Economic School, Stanford University, University of Arizona, Univer-
sity of California at Berkeley, University of Luxembourg, University of Maryland, University of
Minnesota, University of Rochester, the 2013 meetings of the Western Finance Association and
the European Finance Association, and the 2013 UBC Summer Finance Conference. The authors
have no conflicts of interest, as identified in the Disclosure Policy.
1In the cross-section, firms with small market capitalization and a high ratio of fundamentals
to price tend to have high stock returns (Banz (1981), Graham and Dodd (1934)). Fama and
French (1992) provide a detailed analysis of both the value and the size premium. Ang et al.
(2006) document that high idiosyncratic volatility predicts low returns. Among others, Loughran
and Ritter (1995), Daniel and Titman (2006), and Pontiff and Woodgate (2008)showthatstocks
underperform following equity issuance.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12280
425
426 The Journal of Finance R
second division is driven only by systematic shocks. This firm can be viewed as
a portfolio of a zero-beta asset and a risky asset. When a positive idiosyncratic
shock occurs, the size of the zero-beta asset increases, making it a larger frac-
tion of the total portfolio value. As a result, overall firm beta decreases, as do ex-
pected stock returns. Therefore, any firm characteristic correlated with the his-
tory of idiosyncratic cash flow shocks can help explain expected stock returns.
In a more general setting, we show that beta is invariant with respect to
idiosyncratic shocks only in the special case in which profits are the product
of idiosyncratic and systematic profitability shocks. Multiplicative production
functions of this type are used extensively in the literature because of their
tractability properties (see, for example, Gomes, Kogan, and Zhang (2003),
Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), Zhang (2005), and Cooper (2006)).2
Therefore, without additional features such as operating leverage, time-varying
price of risk, or investment options, market betas are independent of firm-
specific shocks.
Using this insight, we build a simple model in which firm value is additive in
two types of shocks and only systematic risk is priced. We first consider a firm
consisting entirely of assets in place. We show that, in the simple benchmark
model, firm characteristics are related to expected returns in the cross-section.
All else being equal, firms with larger idiosyncratic cash flows have larger
market capitalization and lower book-to-market, and at the same time have
lower equity betas. As a result, large firms and growth firms have low expected
returns.
Similarly, we obtain a negative relation between idiosyncratic volatility and
expected stock returns, a puzzling empirical finding in Ang et al. (2006)that
presents a challenge to risk-based explanations of expected stock returns. In
our one-factor model, a history of favorable idiosyncratic shocks decreases the
relative magnitude of the systematic profit component, thereby increasing id-
iosyncratic stock return volatility and lowering beta. Importantly,idiosyncratic
risk is not priced in our framework, but it is negatively correlated with system-
atic risk and can therefore predict returns.
The model, which incorporates systematic and idiosyncratic cash flow shocks,
also adds to our understanding of the relation between growth options and
risk. Since investment options are levered claims on assets in place, they are
usually considered more risky than installed capital.3We demonstrate that
the relation between options and risk depends on the type of investment op-
tion. In particular, while growth options linked to systematic shocks increase a
firm’s risk, growth options linked to idiosyncratic profitability shocks have the
opposite effect. Somewhat surprisingly,however, the exercise of both systematic
2Notable exceptions are Brennan (1973) and Bossaerts and Green (1989), who model dividends
as the sum of persistent idiosyncratic shocks and a single systematic shock. In particular,Bossaerts
and Green (1989) derive two-factor arbitrage pricing theory restrictions on dynamic equilibrium
asset returns to explain the abnormally high January returns of small stocks.
3The existing literature shows that this relation can be reversed in the presence of operating
leverage or adjustment costs. See, among others, Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), Zhang
(2005), Cooper (2006), and Novy-Marx (2011).
Idiosyncratic Cash Flows and Systematic Risk 427
and idiosyncratic growth options always leads to a decline in a firm’s system-
atic risk as long as the firm finances new investment with equity. Thus, our
model also accounts for the observed poor stock return performance following
seasoned equity offerings (Loughran and Ritter (1995)).
Furthermore, growth options magnify the value and size premiums in the
model and give rise to time-varying price-earnings ratios. There are two rea-
sons for these effects. First, options make firm value and conditional beta more
sensitive to profitability shocks, as irreversible investment options grow in
value exponentially (Dixit and Pindyck (1994)). Second, firms optimally exer-
cise their investment options, and as a result lower their risk, only when their
market capitalization is high. We show that the nonlinear exposure of growth
options to the underlying profitability shock can generate price-earnings ratios
that negatively predict returns.
The intuition developed in this paper applies to any setting with a single
source or multiple sources of priced risk. As in previous studies, size and value
effects are not anomalous relative to the correctly specified asset pricing model
and appear only when not all sources of priced risk are accounted for correctly,
as in Berk (1995). Reconciling the predictions of our model with the empirical
evidence on value, size, and idiosyncratic volatility anomalies relative to the
capital asset pricing model (CAPM) thus relies on imperfect measurement of
risk, and in particular on differences between conditional and unconditional
betas, as discussed in Gomes, Kogan, and Zhang (2003). Lewellen and Nagel
(2006) argue that the conditional CAPM cannot match the magnitude of ob-
served anomalies because the variation in estimated betas is not sufficiently
large. However, betas are likely to be mismeasured because either asset pricing
tests fail to use all conditioning information (Hansen and Richard (1987)) or
the proxy for the market portfolio is imperfect (Roll (1977)).
We use analytical solutions from the model to simulate firms’ stock returns
and examine the fit between the model-generated and empirically observed
data. Our analysis of the simulated data indicates that the model can produce
reasonable value and size effects in cross-sectional Fama and MacBeth (1973)
regressions even when we explicitly control for empirically estimated betas. For
example, we find a size premium of 0.48% per month for the decile of stocks with
the smallest market capitalization relative to the largest decile. Sorting based
on book-to-market ratio, price-earnings ratio, and idiosyncratic volatility yields
return differentials of similar magnitudes. Value and size anomalies are more
pronounced when growth options are valuable. These results are consistent
with empirical evidence in Da, Guo, and Jagannathan (2012) and Grullon,
Lyandres, and Zhdanov (2012), who argue that the poor empirical performance
of the unconditional CAPM is largely attributable to real options.
In addition to explaining established asset pricing anomalies, our model
produces novel empirical predictions. In particular, the model suggests that
asset pricing anomalies are stronger when a significant part of cash flows is
idiosyncratic in nature. We test this prediction using portfolios of stocks sorted
by the volatility of their idiosyncratic cash flows and by firm characteristics
such as size and book-to-market. We find that that size and book-to-market

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT