How Do Quasi‐Random Option Grants Affect CEO Risk‐Taking?

Published date01 December 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12545
Date01 December 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2017
How Do Quasi-Random Option Grants Affect
CEO Risk-Taking?
KELLY SHUE and RICHARD R. TOWNSEND
ABSTRACT
We examine how an increase in stock option grants affects CEO risk-taking. The
overall net effect of option grants is theoretically ambiguous for risk-averse CEOs.
To overcome the endogeneity of option grants, we exploit institutional features of
multiyear compensation plans, which generate two distinct types of variation in the
timing of when large increases in new at-the-money options are granted. We find that,
given average grant levels during our sample period, a 10% increase in new options
granted leads to a 2.8% to 4.2% increase in equity volatility. This increase in risk is
driven largely by increased leverage.
PERFORMANCE-SENSITIVE PAY FOR EXECUTIVES has surged over the last 30 years.
Much of this surge has been in the form of stock options, which became the
largest component of executive compensation in the 1990s, accounting for ap-
proximately 50% of the total compensation of S&P 500 CEOs by the end of
the decade. Following changes in the accounting treatment of options in 2005,
the use of options declined. Still, options remain a major component of CEO
pay, accounting for over 20% of total pay (Murphy (2013)). Moreover, Bettis
et al. (2012) find that many firms have substituted from option grants toward
performance-vesting stock grants, which have option-like payoffs. Similar to
an option, a performance-vesting share provides zero payoff below some perfor-
mance threshold and increasing payoffs above the threshold. As of 2008, nearly
Kelly Shue is with YaleUniversity, School of Management and NBER; Richard Townsend (cor-
responding author) is with the University of California San Diego, Rady School of Management.
We are grateful to Michael Roberts (the Editor), the Associate Editor, two anonymous referees,
Marianne Bertrand, Ing-Haw Cheng, Ken French, Ed Glaeser, ToddGormley, Ben Iverson (discus-
sant), Steve Kaplan, Borja Larrain (discussant), Jonathan Lewellen, Katharina Lewellen, David
Matsa (discussant), David Metzger (discussant), TobyMoskowitz, Candice Prendergast, Enrichetta
Ravina (discussant), Amit Seru, and Wei Wang (discussant) for helpful suggestions. We thank
seminar participants at AFA, BYU, CICF Conference, Depaul, Duke, Gerzensee ESSFM, Harvard,
HKUST Finance Symposium, McGill Todai Conference, Finance UC Chile, Helsinki, IDC Herzliya
Finance Conference, NBER Corporate Finance and Personnel Meetings, SEC, Simon Fraser Uni-
versity, Stanford, Stockholm School of Economics, Universityof Amsterdam, UC Berkeley, UCLA,
and Wharton for helpful comments. We thank David Yermack for his generosity in sharing data.
We thank Matt Turner at Pearl Meyer, Don Delves at the Delves Group, and Stephen O’Byrne
at Shareholder Value Advisors for helping us understand the intricacies of executive stock option
plans. Menaka Hampole provided excellent research assistance. We acknowledge financial support
from the Initiative on Global Markets. The authors have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12545
2551
2552 The Journal of Finance R
40% of equity awards were characterized by performance vesting rather than
simple time vesting. Given the prevalence of options and option-like compen-
sation, it is important to understand the extent to which these forms of pay
affect CEO decision-making. In particular, there is a long-standing and impor-
tant question dating back to Jensen and Meckling (1976) of whether options
influence CEO risk-taking behavior.
The idea that stock options create incentives for risk-taking is rooted in the
convexity of their payoffs: if the underlying stock price rises above the strike
price, the option holder earns the difference, but if the stock price drops be-
low the strike price, the option holder does not lose the difference. However,
in addition to this “convexity effect,” Ross (2004) shows that options can have
a countervailing “magnification effect.” The magnification effect is driven by
the fact that options increase the sensitivity of an executive’s wealth to the
underlying stock price, which may lead a risk-averse executive to want to
decrease risk. In practice, it is also possible that options have no effect on
risk-taking if executives are sufficiently well monitored or if they are able to
hedge their option holdings (Garvey and Milbourn (2003)). Thus, the over-
all effect of option compensation on risk-taking is ultimately an empirical
question.1
Estimating the effect of options on risk-taking is difficult due to endogeneity
issues. The main challenge is that an omitted factor could affect both options
and risk-taking. For example, if value-maximizing firms believe that options
increase risk-taking, they may increase option pay exactly when the benefits
to risk-taking are greater (i.e., when there are more risky positive net present
value (NPV) projects). In this case, risk-taking may increase due to option
pay or because the CEO is responding to the firm’s need for more risk-taking.
While much of the existing research on options and risk-taking has been corre-
lational in nature, two recent studies by Chava and Purnanandam (2010)and
Hayes, Lemmon, and Qiu (2012) attempt to address these endogeneity issues
by examining how executive risk-taking changed when option use declined
following the change in the accounting treatment of options in 2005. How-
ever, firms that decreased option compensation after the reform also tended
to increase stock compensation at the same time. As a result, this experiment
is not ideal for isolating the total net effect of options—for risk-averse man-
agers, stock compensation affects risk-taking incentives as well. Furthermore,
Bettis et al. (2012) point out that the confounding effect of the increase in stock
compensation is exacerbated by the fact that much of the stock compensation
was in the form of performance-vesting shares, which have option-like con-
vex payoffs. Finally, the regulatory change affected all firms simultaneously,
so there is no control group available to estimate the counterfactual change
1The magnification effect has also been noted by Lambert, Larcker, and Verrecchia (1991),
Carpenter (2000), Hall and Murphy (2002), and Lewellen (2006), among others. Options may also
have other ambiguous implications for risk. For example, options increase in value with firm
performance, and managers may increase or decrease firm risk in the pursuit of stronger firm
performance. In addition, option compensation increases wealth, which may alter risk tolerance.
How Do Quasi-Random Option Grants Affect CEO Risk-Taking? 2553
in risk-taking that would have occurred over the same time period absent the
reform.2
Toidentify a causal effect of options on risk-taking, the ideal test would utilize
exogenous variation in option pay that is staggered across firms over time. In
this paper, we exploit a natural experiment that delivers such variation. Our
identification strategy builds on Hall’s (1999)) observation that firms often
award options according to multiyear plans. Two types of plans are commonly
used: fixed-number and fixed-value.3Under a fixed-number plan, an executive
receives the same number of options each year within a cycle. Under a fixed-
value plan, an executive receives the same value of options each year within
a cycle. Cycles are generally short, lasting about two years, after which a new
cycle typically begins.
Multiyear plans give us two distinct sources of variation in the timing of
option pay increases. Our first instrumental variables (IV) strategy uses only
CEOs on fixed-value plans. For these executives, option compensation tends
to follow an increasing step function. During a fixed-value cycle, the value of
options granted is held constant. At the beginning of a new cycle, there is a
discrete increase in the value of option grants, on average. The timing of when
these steps occur is staggered across firms. These staggered steps motivate our
first instrument: an indicator variable for whether each CEO-year is predicted
to be the first year of a new fixed-value cycle. We use predicted cycle first years
instead of actual cycle first years as our instrument because the timing of
when new cycles actually begin may be endogenously renegotiated between the
manager and the board. For example, a manager may negotiate to prematurely
start a new cycle for some unobserved reason that also directly relates to the
firm’s risk. Instead, we use a predicted first-year indicator, which corresponds
to when new cycles would likely have started if renegotiation had not taken
place. Our predictions exploit the fact that firms tend to use repeated cycles
of equal length. We use the length of a manager’s previous cycle to predict
when the next cycle will begin. Predictions are therefore based only on past
information. For example, if a manager had cycles starting in 1990 and 1992,
we would predict that a new cycle would start in 1994. Assuming that firms do
not set the length of the current cycle in anticipation of risk-taking conditions
at the start of future cycles, the predicted first year instrument should purge
the estimation of bias from renegotiation.
Our second IV strategy does not use the timing of cycle first years, but
rather uses variation in the value of options granted within fixed-number and
fixed-value cycles. We exploit the fact that the Black-Scholes value of an at-
the-money option increases proportionally with its strike price. As Hall (1999)
2Using a different strategy, Gormley, Matsa, and Milbourn (2013) examine responses to an
exogenous increase in firm litigation risk. The exogenous nature of the shock helps rule out reverse
causality and allows the authors to explore an important related question: how does a change in
risk affect option compensation? However, to identify a causal effect of options on risk-taking, the
ideal test would utilize exogenous variation in option pay rather than in the risk environment.
3Hall (1999) describes multiyear grant cycles in detail, but does not use them as an instrument
to explore the effect of options on managerial behavior.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT