How Do Investment Ideas Spread through Social Interaction? Evidence from a Ponzi Scheme

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12822
AuthorVILLE RANTALA
Published date01 October 2019
Date01 October 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2019
How Do Investment Ideas Spread through Social
Interaction? Evidence from a Ponzi Scheme
VILLE RANTALA
ABSTRACT
A unique data set from a large Ponzi scheme allows me to study word-of-mouth
diffusion of investment information. Investors could join the scheme only by invitation
from an existing member, which allows me to observe how the idea spreads from one
person to the next based on inviter-invitee relationships. I find that the observed
social network has a scale-free connectivity structure, which significantly facilitates
the diffusion of the investment idea and contributes to the growth and survival of
the socially spreading Ponzi scheme. I further find that investors invest more if their
inviter has comparatively higher age, education, and income.
SHILLER (2000,2014)ARGUES THAT INVESTMENT ideas can spread like epidemics
among investors, with asset prices influenced by social dynamics. In this paper,
I examine whether large-scale social contagion effects among investors exist,
and if so, what the information diffusion process looks like.
To do so, I employ a data set in which I directly observe the diffusion of an
investment idea from one person to the next. The data set consists of partici-
pants of a large investment Ponzi scheme, whereby investors could join only by
personal invitation from an existing member, who was referred to as a sponsor.
This feature allows me to study the effect of word-of-mouth information at an
individual level. Information about the scheme was not publicly available, so
Ville Rantala is with the Miami Business School, University of Miami. I am grateful to the
Finnish National Bureau of Investigations for providing the source documents. Parts of this paper
were previously circulated as a separate working paper entitled “Keeping Up with the Ponzis.” I
thank Nick Barberis, Peter Bossaerts, James Choi, Nicholas Christakis, Henrik Cronqvist, Florian
Ederer, Ester Faia, David Hirshleifer,Harrison Hong, Hans Hvide, Markku Kaustia, Matti Kelo-
harju, Samuli Kn¨
upfer, Timo Korkeam¨
aki, George Korniotis, Alok Kumar, Juhani Linnainmaa,
Steffen Meyer, Raghu Rau, Sophie Shive, Scott Weisbenner, Charlotte Østergaard, participants at
the Helsinki Finance Summit 2014, European Finance Association Doctoral Tutorial 2015, Euro-
pean Conference on Household Finance 2015, Conference on Behavioral Aspects of Macroeconomics
and Finance 2015, Miami Behavioral Finance Conference 2015, SFS Cavalcade 2016, American
Economic Association 2017, European Retail Investment Conference 2017; as well as seminar par-
ticipants at BI Norwegian Business School, Cass Business School, Copenhagen Business School,
Georgetown University, HEC Paris, Indiana University, University of Melbourne, University of
Miami, University of New South Wales, Washington University in St. Louis, and Yale University
for helpful comments. I also thank Antti Lehtinen for assistance with geographic information anal-
ysis. I acknowledge financial support from the OP Group Research Foundation. The author does
not have any potential conflicts of interest to disclose, as identified in the Journal of Finance’s
disclosure policy.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12822
2349
2350 The Journal of Finance R
when a new investor joins, I know that he has learned about the opportunity
from the inviter. By observing the inviter-invitee social network, I am able
to examine the process through which an investment idea spreads across a
population.
The investment scheme, Wincapita, was a Finnish investment operation that
was active from 2003 to 2008. Wincapita offered its investors large returns, ini-
tially claiming that the profits were generated by sports betting and later by
currency trading. In reality,it was a classic Ponzi scheme whereby all incoming
cash flows came from new and existing investors, with none of the profits gener-
ated by actual trading or investments. The scheme grew very large, ultimately
growing to over 10,000 members, approximately 0.2% of the total population of
Finland.
The collapse of Wincapita in 2008 led to one of the largest criminal inves-
tigations in Finnish history.1The data used in this study come from the in-
vestigation documents of the Finnish National Bureau of Investigation.2The
documents allow me to identify over 5,000 Wincapita investors and contain
detailed information for over 3,000 investors who were questioned by police. In
addition to details about their investments and withdrawals, these data contain
information on investors’ personal characteristics, such as age, income, loca-
tion, and education. I combine these data with information on their sponsoring
relationships.3Because the data were collected from investors in a formal police
interview, they do not suffer from many of the typical reporting and selection
biases that exist in survey data on social relationships. The interviewing offi-
cer’s responsibility was to collect facts that could be used as evidence in a court
of law.
Several papers provide theoretical models of information diffusion and the
structure of information networks among investors.4I present empirical evi-
dence on these phenomena. In particular, the data allow me to shed light on
the social network structure of information diffusion among investors. Empir-
ical social networks that connect people through different kinds of personal
ties exhibit strong structural regularities and differ significantly from random
graph networks in which the connections between nodes are evenly distributed
1Reported by YLE News on May 5, 2008 (“Wincapitasta tulossa maan laajimpia rikostutkin-
toja.”)
2Finnish National Bureau of Investigation, 2010, Esitutkintap¨
oyt¨
akirja 2400/R/61/10.
3There was a financial incentive to sponsor others. Sponsors received 200 of (virtual) money
for each sponsored investor and 20% of the virtual profits earned by the sponsored investor’s
investments (I discuss this further in Section Ibelow). A sponsor’s sponsor would not receive any
portion of these profits, so Wincapita was not a traditional pyramid scheme whereby the profits
are determined by the investor’s level in the “pyramid.”
4Stein (2008), Han and Yang (2013), and Andrei and Cujean (2017) model the transmission
of information through personal communication between investors. Ozsoylev and Walden (2011)
study the asset pricing implications of large information networks. Shiller and Pound (1989),
Shiller (2000), and Shive (2010) argue that epidemic models can be used to characterize the
diffusion of social interest among investors. For general models of word-of-mouth communication,
see Ellison and Fudenberg (1995), Banerjee and Fudenberg (2004), and Cao, Han and Hirshleifer
(2011).
How Do Investment Ideas Spread through Social Interaction? 2351
(see Jackson and Rogers (2007) for a review). However, because the diffusion
of word-of-mouth information is typically unobservable, there is little evidence
on whether these structures play a role in the diffusion of information within
the networks. In social networks, the distribution of connections per node
typically has a heavy right tail, and the average node to node distances are
short. I find that both of these characteristics exist in the diffusion process of
Wincapita.
In particular, the distribution of the number of connections per node in Win-
capita’s sponsoring network decays approximately as a power law. The empir-
ical probability of sponsoring kinvestors is proportional to the power of k,so
that P(k)kγwhere γis a constant. The power-law characteristic is visu-
ally apparent in a log-log plot, and Kolmogorov-Smirnov test statistics based
on a fitted power-law model strongly support the view that the data follow a
power law. Networks with this structure are known as scale-free networks,
and power-law distributions are very common in empirical social networks
(Barab´
asi (2009)). Here, the power law indicates that a small minority of in-
vestors are responsible for most of the social effect.
I compare Wincapita’s actual sponsoring network to a simulated random
network and find that the power-law topology has a dramatic effect on the rate
at which information spreads. The random network has the same number of
investors, the same percentage of sponsors, and the same average number of
sponsored investors per sponsor. The only difference compared to the actual
network is that the distribution of the number of sponsored investors follows
a Poisson distribution instead of the power law, as in the model of Erd˝
os and
Renyi (1959). The results show that an epidemic that spreads through the
Wincapita network one step at a time reaches all investors in 15 steps. In
comparison, in the simulated network, it takes an average of 161 network steps
to reach the same number of investors. When I calibrate a simple Ponzi scheme
model to both networks, I find that the actual network can sustain significantly
higher payouts relative to investors’ investments without collapsing.
The network structure also provides information about the diffusion dynam-
ics of Wincapita. I find that the cumulative number of investors as a function
of network distance from the originator of the scheme follows an S-shaped
curve. The S-curve implies that information diffusion within social networks
progresses in a nonlinear fashion.
I next analyze how social connections within the scheme are related to par-
ticipants’ investment decisions. After controlling for personal characteristics
and inviter fixed effects, I find that investors invest statistically significantly
more if their inviter has comparatively higher income, age, and education.
The marginal effect of the inviter’s income is highest when it is just above
the invitee’s income, suggesting that it may be a reference point in decision
making. I also find that sponsors invest more than nonsponsors, which in-
dicates that social behavior and investment behavior are correlated among
investors.
This paper contributes to the literature in several ways. First, I show that an
investment idea can spread across the population through social interaction,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT