Hospital performance standards and medical pricing: The impact of information disclosure in cardiac care

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12381
AuthorAvi Dor,William Encinosa,Kathleen Carey
Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:492515.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems492
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 17 April 2018
|
Revised: 21 February 2020
|
Accepted: 6 May 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12381
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Hospital performance standards and medical pricing: The
impact of information disclosure in cardiac care
Avi Dor
1,2
|William Encinosa
3
|Kathleen Carey
4
1
Department of Health Policy and
Management, George Washington
University and NBER, Washington,
District of Columbia
2
NBER, Washington, District of Columbia
3
Center for Financing, Access, and Cost
Trends, Agency for Healthcare Research
and Quality and Georgetown University,
Rockville, Maryland
4
Department of Health Policy and
Management, Boston University, Boston,
Massachusetts
Correspondence
Avi Dor, Department of Health Policy and
Management,George Washington
University and NBER, Washington,
District of Columbia.
Email: avidor@gwu.edu
William Encinosa, Center for Financing,
Access, and Cost Trends, Agency for
Healthcare Research and Quality and
Georgetown University, Rockville,
Maryland.
Email: william.encinosa@ahrq.hhs.gov
Funding information
Agency for Healthcare Research and
Quality, Grant/Award Number:
R01 HS02361001
Abstract
A policy concern is that the initiation of Hospital Compare (HC) reporting in
Medicare provided leverage to insurers in price negotiations for lowering
private sector prices without regard to hospital performance. Using the se-
quential Nash bargaining framework we provide economic intuition to the
contrary: while average hospital prices decline under quality disclosures,
hospitals with aboveaverage quality are able to exert a stronger bargaining
position, consequently capturing prices above the market rate. To explore
this issue empirically we estimate variants of differenceindifference
models, examining the effects of the three main scores (heart attack, heart
failure, and combined mortalities) on transaction prices of related hospital
procedures. States which had similar mandated reporting systems in place
before the initiation of HC form the control group. Analyzing claims data
of privately insured patients, we find that HC exerted downward pressure
on prices. However, hospitals rated aboveaveragecaptured higher
prices, thereby offsetting the overall policy effect fully or partially. Leads
andlagsanalysislendsfurther support for our differenceindifference
approach. We find that highly ranked hospitals received a quality
premium of 814%, comparable to price effects found in other health care
markets. We conclude that HC was effective at constraining prices without
penalizing high performers.
KEYWORDS
differenceindifference models, information rents, medical care, Nash bargaining, pricing and
product quality
1|INTRODUCTION
1.1 |Motivation
Consumer information in the form of hospital rating systems known as report cardshave been in existence in various
forms as early as the 1990s. However, such report cards were made available in a small number of states that generated
them independently from each other, while employing a mix of measures and ranking methodologies. In 2005, the
Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) launched a uniform online national rating system, known as
Hospital Compare (HC), aimed at informing consumers and promoting competition among hospitals. Initially, HC
consisted of a set of process measures of hospital performance based on general practices.
1
In 2008, these were
augmented with outcomebased measures, namely mortalitybased hospital rankings which were deemed to be more
easily understood by patients and also more effective at motivating hospitals to engage in quality improvement practices
(Harris, 2007). Initially these outcome measures focused primarily on cardiac care. Outcomes for other medical con-
ditions were gradually phased in after 2012.
In practice, opinion surveys have shown that consumers were generally unaware or uninterested in these
rankings, even as they had become more accessible, and there is little evidence in the empirical literature to suggest
that hospital report cards had an impact on consumer choices of hospitals. Similarly, there is little evidence that
HC and other report cards have had a significant impact on patient outcomes. We briefly review the literature
below.
A less explored channel through which public reporting might impact health care markets, and ultimately
patients, is hospital pricing. In the private segment of the health care market, private insurers rather than in-
dividual patients incur the bulk of health care costs. As group purchasers, large insurance firms and managed care
organizations who engage in price negotiations with hospitals are more likely to incorporate information from
public reporting in their decisionmaking (Dor, Encinosa, & Carey, 2015;Reinhardt,2006,2009). However, there is
a paucity of evidence on the impact of report cards on hospital pricing. Yet, in a wellfunctioning market, a
hospital's ability to deliver better health outcomes could be expected to lead to greater demand and a more
advantageous bargaining position for the hospital, and hence be rewarded by higher prices. In this paper, we
provide economic intuition for this expectation using a simple hospitalinsurer bargaining model (Garmon, 2017;
Gowrisankaran, Nevo, & Town, 2015;Lewis&Pflum,2015), augmenting the sequential Nash Bargaining model to
account for consumer valuation of quality when there are third party payers (Dafny, Ho, & Lee, 2019). To address
the empirical gap we examine the impact of implementing quality reporting on inpatient prices, allowing for
hospital differentiation by relativerankings.Specifically,weestimatetheimpactoftheHCmeasures,asim-
plemented in 2008, on actual prices negotiated and transacted between private insurers and U.S. hospitals. These
HC measures are categorical rankings based on hospital riskadjusted mortality rates for the three medical con-
ditions made available online as of 2008, which included heart attack, heart failure, and pneumonia. We focus on
prices of major cardiac procedures related to heart attacks and heart failure. Results suggest that HC exerts
downward pressure on prices, but that this effect is offset for hospitals ranked in the highest quality category.
These results differ from an older strand of literature in industrial organization theory. Matthews and Postlewaite
(1985)andSchlee(1996) show that quality information can harm consumers because the seller raises the price too
much after information disclosure. Our theory differs in that we model Nash bargaining of prices, rather than
monopoly or duopoly prices (see Ma & Mak, 2014, for a Bertrand competition case).
A main contribution of our paper is to bridge the gap between two important literatures to shed new light on the
impact of quality reports on prices. First, we use the contemporary literature on Nash bargaining, which has emerged as
the primary vehicle for modeling hospitalinsurer prices. While this has led to many new insights into the impact of
hospital mergers on prices (Garmon, 2017; Gowrisankaran et al., 2015; Ho & Lee, 2017; Lewis & Pflum, 2015). it has
been silent on the interaction between quality and price. Second, we incorporate the literature on the role of quality
disclosures which focused heavily on the impact of quality reports on consumers, while remaining relatively silent on
prices (for a review, see Dranove and Jin, 2010). For example, Jin (2005) and Jin, Zhe, and Sorensen (2006) find that
some health maintenance organizations (HMOs) voluntarily reported National Committee for Quality Assurance
(NCQA) quality measures to differentiate their product in the market, and that this was of high value to consumers.
2
Additionally, Jin, Zhe, and Leslie (2003) find that the public reporting of restaurant hygiene grade cards improve health
outcomes, by reducing hospitalizations from foodborne diseases by 20%. We connect these two strands of literature by
introducing quality disclosure into the standard Nash bargaining model to explore the impact of quality disclosure on
price negotiations.
1.2 |Impacts of HC public reporting of hospital performance
Information about hospital quality performance began appearing in the public domain in the 1990s, albeit limited to
several states and using disparate methodologies. An early review of the gains from public disclosure of performance
data found that consumers showed little interest in or use of the available information due to various behavioral factors
(Marshall, Shekelle, Leatherman, & Brook, 2000). Anecdotal surveys of hospital administrators and executives have
DOR ET AL.
|
493

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT