Higher Order Effects in Asset Pricing Models with Long‐Run Risks

AuthorOLE WILMS,WALTER POHL,KARL SCHMEDDERS
Published date01 June 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12615
Date01 June 2018
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIII, NO. 3 JUNE 2018
Higher Order Effects in Asset Pricing Models
with Long-Run Risks
WALTER POHL, KARL SCHMEDDERS, and OLE WILMS
ABSTRACT
This paper shows that the latest generation of asset pricing models with long-run risk
exhibit economically significant nonlinearities, and thus the ubiquitous Campbell-
Shiller log-linearization can generate large numerical errors. These errors translate
in turn to considerable errors in the model predictions, for example, for the mag-
nitude of the equity premium or return predictability. We demonstrate that these
nonlinearities arise from the presence of multiple highly persistent processes, which
cause the exogenous states to attain values far away from their long-run means with
nonnegligible probability. These extreme values have a significant impact on asset
price dynamics.
BANSAL AND YARON (2004)INTRODUCE TWO important innovations to the as-
set pricing literature. In particular, they put forward an economic mechanism
based on long-run risk to explain many empirical asset pricing facts, and they
demonstrate that the Campbell-Shiller (1988) log-linearization technique pro-
vides a simple method for analyzing such models. These two contributions
together have served as the foundation for a large literature on the ability of
long-run risk to solve empirical puzzles. By necessity,log-linearization neglects
higher order effects in asset pricing models. In this paper, we ask whether these
effects matter for the latest generation of long-run risk models. We show that
they do. More specifically, we demonstrate that, for many economically plau-
sible choices of parameters and exogenous processes, the errors introduced by
log-linearization can themselves be economically significant. In fact, for highly
persistent processes, as regularly used in the literature, the approximation
errors in moments can exceed 70%.
Walter Pohl is with Department of Finance, NHH Norwegian School of Economics. Karl
Schmedders is with Department of Business Administration, University of Zurich. Ole Wilms
is with Department of Finance, Tilburg University.This paper was previously circulated under the
title “Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences.” We are grate-
ful to two anonymous referees, an anonymous Associate Editor, and the Editor, Stefan Nagel, for
thoughtful reviews of earlier versions. We are indebted to Nicole Branger,Lars Hansen, Ken Judd,
Martin Lettau, Malte Schumacher, Che-Lin Su, and particularly our discussant Alexis Akira Toda
for helpful discussions on the subject. We thank seminar audiences at the University of Zurich, the
Becker Friedman Institute, the University of M¨
unster, and various conferences for comments. We
are grateful to the copy editor, Brenda Priebe, for excellent editorial support. Ole Wilms gratefully
acknowledges financial support from the Z¨
urcher Universit¨
atsverein. The authors do not have any
conflicts of interest as per the Journal of Finance disclosure policy.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12615
1061
1062 The Journal of Finance R
Asset pricing models have become increasingly complex over the last three
decades. The first generation of such models, developed in the 1980s (Grossman
and Shiller (1981), Hansen and Singleton (1982), Mehra and Prescott (1985)),
proved inadequate in explaining key features of financial markets, such as
the high equity premium and the low risk-free rate. As the literature on asset
pricing has evolved and matured over time, researchers have added more com-
plex elements to their models such as incomplete markets (e.g., uninsurable
income risks), frictions (e.g., borrowing or collateral constraints), time-varying
risk aversion, and heterogeneous expectations. While these additional features
have had varying degrees of success, the new generation of long-run risk mod-
els (e.g., Bansal and Yaron (2004) or Hansen, Heaton, and Li (2008)), with
their interplay of persistent components in consumption growth and recursive
preferences, have had considerably more success in resolving long-standing
asset pricing puzzles. The key feature of these models is the combination of a
preference for the early resolution of risk together with highly persistent state
processes that potentially affect long-run model outcomes.
Complex models generally require numerical solution techniques. Bansal
and Yaron (2004) show that a simple linearized solution method based on the
Campbell-Shiller (1988) present-value relation works well for their original
model because the log price-dividend ratio in the model is approximately a lin-
ear function of the underlying shocks. Additionally,the linearization procedure
has the attractive property of lending itself to a simple analysis of the economic
impact of different shocks. This property is particularly appealing as it allows
the researcher to draw conclusions about parameter dependencies and eco-
nomic mechanisms in the model. Accordingly,a large group of researchers have
followed Bansal and Yaron (2004) and used the log-linearization technique to
solve asset pricing models with recursive preferences (e.g., Bollerslev,Tauchen,
and Zhou (2009), Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron(2010), Koijen et al. (2010), Constan-
tinides and Ghosh (2011), Drechsler and Yaron(2011), Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron
(2012), Beeler and Campbell (2012), Bansal and Shaliastovich (2013), Bansal
et al. (2014), and Segal, Shaliastovich, and Yaron (2015), among others). Ex-
amining this strand of literature, it is difficult to find studies that do not rely
on the Campbell-Shiller (1988) approach1—it has become the standard method
for solving asset pricing models with long-run risk.
To better match features of the data, the tendency in the long-run risk liter-
ature has been toward both higher persistence and greater model complexity.
This development suggests that it is time to take stock of whether the Campbell-
Shiller (1988) approximation is still appropriate. To address this question, we
first identify the factors that can make higher order dynamics matter for the
benchmark long-run risk model with stochastic volatility. We show that, for
1Prominent exceptions that do not rely on log-linearized solutions are the studies by Croce, Let-
tau, and Ludvigson (2015) and Collin-Dufresne, Johannes, and Lochstoer (2016). Kaltenbrunner
and Lochstoer (2010) use log-linearized solutions to infer qualitative model implications but use
value function iteration for their quantitative results. They approximate the value function with
Chebyshev polynomials.
Higher Order Effects in Asset Pricing Models with Long-Run Risks 1063
highly persistent processes, these effects do matter. Economically, when shocks
are highly persistent, agents can spend longer periods trapped in undesirable
parts of the state space, which can have a large impact on investor behavior.The
problem is particularly severe when both long-run risk and stochastic volatility
are persistent. In that case, the interaction between long-run risk and stochas-
tic volatility becomes especially significant when the long-run growth rate is
low but the volatility of the growth rate is high, which in turn creates signif-
icant deviations from linearity. As a side effect, this interaction leads to large
errors in predictability regressions using simulated data: the log-linearized so-
lutions overstate the predictability of returns and understate the predictability
of dividends by the log price-dividend ratio, relative to a higher precision so-
lution. Interestingly, the persistence is a problem only in the presence of a
strong preference for the early resolution of risk. However, without a prefer-
ence for the early resolution of risk, it is difficult to generate a high equity
premium.
To show that this nonlinearity matters for real models, and is not just an
intellectual exercise, we examine the consequences of ignoring nonlinear dy-
namics in the Bansal and Yaron (2004) model as well as five other recent stud-
ies, namely, the newly calibrated version of Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron (2012),
the extensive calibration study of Schorfheide, Song, and Yaron (2018), the
volatility-of-volatility model of Bollerslev, Xu, and Zhou (2015), and the studies
on real and nominal bonds of Koijen et al. (2010) and Bansal and Shalias-
tovich (2013). We show that the higher order dynamics not captured by the
Campbell-Shiller (1988) approximation can be large and economically signifi-
cant. For example, for the calibration of Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron (2012), which
is an improved calibration of the original Bansal and Yaron (2004) model (in
particular, with greater persistence in shocks to stochastic volatility), we find
that the log-linearization introduces economically significant errors in model
predictions. The equity premium, for instance, is overestimated by about 100
bps and the relative error in the volatility of the price-dividend ratio exceeds
20%. The true amount of return predictability is approximately half of what
log-linearization would suggest.
In the Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron (2012) model, most of the nonlinearities
are introduced by the pricing of equities, and using a linearized solution for
the stochastic discount factor does not lead to economically significant errors.
This approach does not generally work, however; for other model specifications
analyzed in this paper, we find significant errors in the stochastic discount
factor. Therefore, linearized solutions should not be used for any of the return
equations without carefully testing its accuracy for the specific asset pricing
model under consideration.
Schorfheide, Song, and Yaron (2018) perform a Bayesian estimation of the
model using the same approximation and find evidence of higher persistence
for long-run risk. In this case, we find approximation errors as large as 70% for
some key model moments for the 95% quantiles of the state persistence param-
eters (for the median estimates they are significantly lower). When persistence
is very high, log-linearization can actually invert the slope of the yield curve in

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT