Graduate education and long‐term inventive performance: Evidence from undergraduates' choices during recessions

AuthorKoichiro Onishi,Sadao Nagaoka
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12382
Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:465491. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
465
Received: 12 February 2019
|
Revised: 18 May 2020
|
Accepted: 20 May 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12382
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Graduate education and longterm inventive performance:
Evidence from undergraduates' choices during recessions
Koichiro Onishi
1
|Sadao Nagaoka
2,3
1
Faculty of Education and Integrated Arts
and Science, Waseda University,
Shinjyukuku, Tokyo, Japan
2
Faculty of Economics, Tokyo Keizai
University, Kokubunjishi, Tokyo, Japan
3
Research Institute of Economy, Trade,
and Industry, Chiyodaku, Tokyo, Japan
Correspondence
Koichiro Onishi, Faculty of Education and
Integrated Arts and Science, Waseda
University, 161 Nishiwaseda,
Shinjyukuku, Tokyo 1698050, Japan.
Email: onishi@waseda.jp
Funding information
Japan Society for the Promotion of
Science, Grant/Award Numbers:
JP15K03486, JP26285055
Abstract
Using individuals' lifecycle invention data, we investigate how graduate
education affects inventive performance and inventors' abilities to absorb and
combine diverse knowledge sources. To control for the endogeneity of edu-
cational choice, we use the status of college labor markets as an instrumental
variable (IV), specifically the difference between the unemployment rate and
its longrun average rate by academic field. We find that graduate education,
induced by the IV, significantly enhances inventive performance and the scope
of exploited knowledge, exceeding the levels implied by ordinary least squares.
Graduate education can have a significant causal effect on inventive capability
and performance.
1|INTRODUCTION
Human resources are often seen as central to creating inventions and, therefore, to knowledgebased economic growth.
On the theoretical front, endogenous growth theory identifies the number of highly educated persons in a society as a
key determinant of the growth rate (as pioneered by Romer, 1990). Both emerging and developed countries have
expanded their graduate education programs (at the master's and doctoral levels) based on this view (OECD, 2016,
p. 146). Despite the widespread belief that graduate education enhances inventive performance, there is surprisingly
little empirical support for this conjecture.
1
To fill this important gap, we identify the effect of graduate education on the number and quality of inventions
made by inventors because of this education. We suggest that these additional inventions reflect how well graduate
education nurtures inventors' knowledge absorption capabilities and their inventive productivity. The ability to absorb
scientific advances is a particularly important consideration in the assessment of graduate education's contribution to
inventor performance, given that the absorptive capability is an important determinant of the innovative capability of a
firm (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989; March, 1991). Further, since innovation is often created by recombining existing
knowledge (Schumpeter, 1977; Weitzman, 1998), one can expect individuals with higher education to be able to
combine existing knowledge more effectively. On the other hand, successful technologies and ideas have often arisen
without the influence of existing scientific knowledge (Price, 1965).
To assess the contribution of graduate education, we focused on more than 2,200 Japanese corporate inventors and
derived detailed personal information from the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI) Inventor
Survey. To capture these people's longterm inventive activities, we gathered all the lifecycle patents applications they
had submitted to the Japan Patent Office (JPO).
2
Then, we matched the two databases using the inventors' names,
addresses, and other details. We thus obtained data on the inventors' final educational degrees and their longterm
inventive activities.
Obtaining causal evidence of the effects of education is challenging because an individual's level of education is
endogenous to their unobserved characteristics (superior students would go to graduate school). To control for this
possible selfselection problem, we use the unemployment rate of college graduates in academic fields in the year
preceding the focal inventor's graduation as an instrumental variable (IV). Graduate school seems to be an important
alternative for students facing a negative labor market at the time of college graduation. They may spend their time in
graduate school until the labor market recovers, and a recession can decrease the opportunity costs for attending
graduate school (Charles, Hurst, & Notowidigdo, 2018; Laeven & Popov, 2016). Prior studies have found that labor
market conditions affect enrollment for graduate school and doctoral programs in the United States (Bedard &
Herman, 2008; Johnson, 2013; Shu et al., 2012). Further, Kondo (2007) found a negative correlation between a lower
local job opening ratio and the propensity of high school students to go to college in Japan. Thus, unemployment is a
promising candidate for an instrument.
The unemployment rate of college graduates works as a valid instrument if it affects longterm inventive activities
only through its effect on the choice for graduate education (the exclusion restriction). To control for this possibility
through the changes in technological opportunities and demandside opportunities, we introduce a full set of cross
terms between invention year dummies and technological area dummies. In addition, we addressed the following two
potentially important confounding factors. The first is that college students' unemployment rate could be correlated
with longterm technological opportunities for inventions across academic fields. For example, an academic subject
experiencing rapid scientific progress provides abundant future inventive opportunities and may attract many capable
students; however, unemployment may also be high due to the lag between scientific advances and industrial in-
vestment. To control for this possibility, we focus on the variation within academic fields rather than the level
differences across fields because our instrument is the difference between the unemployment rate and its average rate
in each academic field divided by the standard deviation. Furthermore, we introduce a time trend for each academic
field in the estimations to control for the variations of trends across academic fields. The second confounding factor is
that labor market conditions may directly affect the quality of inventors, because hiring is restricted during a recession,
and therefore, their future inventive performance. However, we will show that a recession in the year preceding
graduation does not affect students' longrun probability of a college graduate ultimately becoming an inventor in
Japan. This is perhaps because students can postpone entering the labor market by choosing to go to a graduate school
when hiring is limited. Furthermore, they can change their jobs over time to realize their aspirations for becoming
inventors. Because there is no reason for us to expect that the students who chose graduate education only due to poor
labor market situation had better inventiveness (e.g., ability, persistence, interest, etc.) than those who could find a job
immediately after the college graduation, we assume that the effect of unemployment fluctuation on the decision to
undertake further graduate education is unrelated to the factors that affect inventiveness.
In this paper, we aim to identify the effect of graduate education on students who would have chosen to become
inventors irrespective of their taking graduate education. That is, we seek to uncover the additional effect of acquiring a
graduate degree, conditional on inventor status (intensive margin). Graduate education can also affect a nation's
inventive performance by enhancing college graduates' propensities to become inventors, as some of them may have
become inventors only due to attending graduate school (extensive margin). This is beyond the focus of our paper due to
data limitations. However, assessing the intensive margin of graduate education itself would be an important con-
tribution to understanding its role, especially because some policy and management decisions depend only on intensive
margins, such as the choice between onthejob training and graduate education.
While our IV (unemployment) can induce effects due to both the intensive and extensive margin, our IV estimation
generates an estimate equivalent to the intensive margin as long as additional inventors who become inventors only
because of their graduate educations have the same capabilities on average as those of the other inventors. Given this
assumption, the extensive margin does not affect our estimate for the intensive margin (proof given in Appendix A).
Even if such an assumption does not hold, it is likely that the additional inventors, due to the extensive margin, have
lower capabilities and smaller graduate education effects than the other inventors. In this case, our IV estimation gives
the lower bound of the intensive margin of graduate education.
In summary, we find that the inventive productivities of inventors with graduate education, as revealed by an IV, are
about 4547% higher than those with less education. These graduateeducated inventors also cite more scientific
literature and build on more diverse fields of prior patent literature. Further, the results in the IV estimation are larger
than those in ordinary least squares (OLS), showing that a significant negative selection exists in college students'
466
|
ONISHI AND NAGAOKA

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT