Franchisee Associations as Sources of Bargaining Power? Some Evidence

AuthorNicholas Argyres,Janet Bercovitz
Date01 October 2015
Published date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12111
Franchisee Associations as Sources of Bargaining
Power? Some Evidence
NICHOLAS ARGYRES
Olin Business School, Washington University in St. Louis
One Brookings Drive, Campus Box 1133, St. Louis, MO 63130
argyres@wustl.edu
JANET BERCOVITZ
College of Business
University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
1206 South Sixth Street, Champaign, IL 61820
jbercov@illinois.edu
The empirical literature in economics and strategy on contract structure, including on franchise
contract structure, has been largely based on agency and transaction cost theories. The effects
of bargaining power have been much less studied. This paper considers the role of independent
franchisee associations in franchising relationships as a means to test for the presence of bargain-
ing power effects. We find that the presence or absence of a franchisee association is significantly
related to each of three key contractual and relationship characteristics: contract duration, non-
compete stringency, and terminations/nonrenewals. This suggests that bargaining power should
be accounted for in studies of contract structure and relationship outcomes.
1. Introduction
The empirical literature in economics and strategy on contracting, and on franchise
contracting in particular, has been largely guided by either the agency model or by
transaction cost economics. These efficiency-oriented theories have been shown to ex-
plain critical categories of contract structure, such as contract duration, payment terms,
equity participation, and restrictions of various kinds.1Very few studies, however, have
examined the impact of bargaining power on contract structure in general, or franchise
contracting in particular.2Yet understanding the role of bargaining power in contracting
is critical for understanding the strategies of contracting firms.
In this paper, we explore the relationships between the existence of independent
franchisee associations and: (1) key terms of business format franchise contracts, and
(2) termination of franchisees. Independent franchisee associations are self-organized
groups of franchisees belonging to the same franchise system that are not sponsored
by the franchisor. (In contrast, franchisee advisory councils consist of representatives of
We are grateful to the American Association of Franchisees & Dealers (AAFD) for data on franchisee asso-
ciations used in the paper, and to Bob Purvin and Peter Hanson, for valuable conversations. We also thank
Dan Elfenbein, Kyle Mayer,Lamar Pierce, St `
ephane Saussier,and participants the International Society for the
New Institutional Economics and Atlanta Competitive Advantage conferences. Finally, we thank an editor
and two anonymous reviewers for many helpful comments.
1. Examples include: Joskow (1985, 1987), Masten and Crocker (1985), Crocker and Masten (1988),
Lafontaine (1992), Lafontaine and Slade (1997), Brickley (1999), Arru˜
nada et al. (2001), Brickley et al. (2006).
2. Exceptions include Michael (2000) for franchising, and Lerner and Merges (1998) for contracts in
biotechnology.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 4, Winter 2015, 811–832
812 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
franchisees chosen by the franchisor.) We study whether independent franchisee asso-
ciations provide a vehicle for the exercise of franchisee bargaining power by examining
whether franchise systems in which franchisee associations are active feature contract
terms and/or termination outcomes that favor franchisees. To our knowledge, no other
empirical study has considered the role of independent franchisee associations in fran-
chising relationships.
A pure efficiency perspective would suggest that each key term in a franchise
contract is determined by agency or transaction cost considerations. The predictions of
a bargaining power perspective would be less specific, suggesting that some provisions
might be impacted by such power, and some might not, depending on the relative
bargaining power of the parties.3For example, franchisees may gain enough bargaining
power, or choose to employ bargaining power, to affect certain provisions in their favor,
but not others. In addition, beyond affecting contractual provisions, bargaining power
might also have effects on actions taken by a franchisor that serve its interest at the
expense of a franchisee, or vice versa. Findings such as these could indicate the presence
of bargaining power, and therefore signal a need to augment theoretical approaches
common in economics and strategy.
We study the relationshipbetween bargaining power – as proxied by the existence
of an independent franchisee organization – and two contractual provisions that, accord-
ing to industry publications and trade groups, are of significant interest to franchisees:
contract duration and franchisor rights to restrict competition from former franchisees.
We also study its relationship with franchisor actions (termination and non–renewal of
franchisees) that can severely harm franchisees’ interests.
We proceed by briefly reviewing the literature on franchise contracting. We then
provide background on independent franchisee associations and underlying sources of
franchisee bargaining power. We develop our hypotheses regarding the impact of these
bargaining power considerations on contract duration and the stringency of noncompete
clauses, as well as franchisor termination behavior. Next, we describe our data and
methods, present and discuss our results, and offer directions for future research.
2. Efficiency of Franchise Contracts
Business format franchising is an organizational form in which a franchisor licenses
a franchisee the right to use the trademarked brand name owned by the franchisor. In
addition to the brand name, franchisees adopt the franchisor’s “business format,” which
can include selling specified products, using specified signage and operating methods,
purchasing specified inputs from the franchisor, etc. Franchisees typically pay the fran-
chisor an upfront fixed fee for the rights to the format, as well as a royalty calculated as
a percentage of the franchisee’s revenues. Franchisees also invest in franchisor-specific
property improvement and advertising campaigns, as well as in training that is largely
franchisor-specific.
Business format franchising offers potential franchisees an opportunity to purchase
and run a proven business of which he/she is the sole owner, or “residual claimant.”
This residual claimant status implies that the franchisee is highly financially motivated
to exert effort in the running of the business – more financially motivated than if the
franchisee were instead an employee of a company-owned outlet. The franchisor benefits
3. This kind of general prediction can be found, for example, in Aghion and Tirole (1994).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT