Expected Inflation and Other Determinants of Treasury Yields

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12700
AuthorGREGORY R. DUFFEE
Date01 October 2018
Published date01 October 2018
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIII, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2018
Expected Inflation and Other Determinants
of Treasury Yields
GREGORY R. DUFFEE
ABSTRACT
Shocks to nominal bond yields consist of news about expected future inflation, ex-
pected future real short rates, and expected excess returns—all over the bond’s life. I
estimate the magnitude of the first component for short- and long-maturity Treasury
bonds. At a quarterly frequency, variances of news about expected inflation account
for between 10% to 20% of variances of yield shocks. Standard dynamic models with
long-run risk imply variance ratios close to 1. Habit formation models fare somewhat
better. The magnitudes of shocks to real rates and expected excess returns cannot be
determined reliably.
ALARGE AND EXPANDING LITERATURE explores the relation between nominal bond
yields and inflation. In a particularly important contribution, Ang and Piazzesi
(2003) introduce Gaussian macro-finance dynamic term structure models to
determine the compensation investors require to face shocks to inflation and
macroeconomic activity. Subsequent studies have branched out to include un-
spanned macro risks, non-Gaussian dynamics, and fundamental explanations
for inflation risk premia that are grounded in investor preferences and New
Keynesian macro models. Yet it is difficult to uncover from this literature any
widely accepted conclusions about the joint dynamics of inflation and the nom-
inal term structure. Motivated by this point, Ang, Bekaert, and Wei (2008)
attempt to produce some basic facts. More recent research does not converge
on their conclusions or any other set of core results. Thus, it remains unclear
which branches of the macro-finance literature are likely to be fruitful and
which should be abandoned.
In this paper, I make an additional attempt to identify a robust empirical
property that can be used to guide future research. I focus on the question
“How large are shocks to expected inflation relative to shocks to nominal bond
yields?” Embedded in this question is an accounting identity. Campbell and
Ammer (1993) show that the shock to a nominal bond’s yield equals the sum
of news about expected inflation, expected short-term real rates, and expected
excess returns, all over the life of the bond. The “inflation variance ratio,” as
Gregory R. Duffee is with Johns Hopkins University. I thank seminar participants at many
schools and conferences, Ravi Bansal, Mike Chernov, Anna Cieslak, George Constantinides, Lars
Lochstoer,Kenneth Singleton (Editor), Jonathan Wright, and three anonymous referees for helpful
comments. I thank especially the discussants Anh Le and Scott Joslin. I have read the Journal of
Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12700
2139
2140 The Journal of Finance R
defined here, is the variance of expected inflation news relative to the variance
of the yield shock.
Three observations motivate a focus on this ratio. First, it can be estimated
without much structure, using survey forecasts of inflation to identify revisions
in inflation expectations. Second, ratios based on quarterly U.S. data are reli-
able, in the sense that standard errors are tight and estimates are reasonably
stable over time. Third, ratios inferred from these data are strongly at odds
with corresponding values from both endowment economy long-run risk models
and standard New Keynesian dynamic models.
Results for the 10-year horizon are representative. During the past 35 years,
the standard deviation of quarterly shocks to 10-year average expected in-
flation is in the neighborhood of 20 basis points. The standard deviation of
quarterly shocks to the 10-year bond yield is much larger—around 60 basis
points. Squaring and dividing produces a variance ratio estimate close to 10%.
The challenge for economists is easier to see when viewing the result from
a different angle. In the data, shocks to nominal yields are large and driven
primarily by a combination of news about expected short-term real rates and
expected excess returns. In our benchmark macro-finance models, channels for
both types of news are small.
Bansal and Yaron (2004) develop one of these benchmark models, combining
a representative agent, recursive utility preferences, and persistent fluctua-
tions in the endowment growth rate. Short-term real rates are driven largely
by fluctuations in expected consumption growth. The long-run risk literature
follows Bansal and Yaron (2004) by relying on a high elasticity of intertempo-
ral substitution and fairly small shocks to expected growth. The combination
of these properties results in low volatility of news about expected short-term
real rates.
These conditionally log-normal models generate news about expected excess
returns only through shocks to conditional volatilities of macroeconomic shocks.
The amount of news this mechanism produces depends on the average level of
bond risk premia, which are much too small to allow for sizable volatilities of
news about expected excess returns.
Dynamic New Keynesian models also produce low volatilities of real rate
news because the dynamics are not sufficiently persistent. Since these models
do not have conditional log-normal dynamics, nonlinearities can potentially
create more news about expected excess returns than can models in the tradi-
tion of Bansal and Yaron(2004). But for parameterized models in the literature,
the nonlinearities are not sufficient to generate realistic volatilities of shocks
to yields.
Habit formation preferences in the spirit of Campbell and Cochrane (1999)
break the link between expected consumption growth and short-term real rates,
creating another mechanism for generating real rate news. In addition, the
models’ nonlinearities can create substantial news about expected excess re-
turns. We can therefore choose parameterizations of these models that are
consistent with observed inflation variance ratios. However, the evidence is
much too tentative to warrant the conclusion that nominal bond dynamics are
Expected Inflation and Treasury Yields 2141
best understood through the lens of habit formation. In particular, parame-
terizations that are successful in reproducing inflation variance ratios exhibit
other properties that appear implausible.
Empirically, innovations to expected short-term real rates and expected ex-
cess returns are the primary drivers of yield shocks. Unfortunately, there is
insufficient information in the data to disentangle the relative contributions of
these two components, at least without imposing restrictive assumptions. The
relevant properties of the data are easy to summarize. Shocks to short-term
real rates are large, and long-term nominal yields covary strongly with them.
If short-term real rates are highly persistent, then the variation in long-term
yields is explained by shocks to average expected future short-term real rates.
If short-term real rates die out quickly, the variation is explained by shocks
to expected excess returns—also called shocks to term premia—that positively
covary with short-term real rates. Point estimates of the persistence are con-
sistent with the latter version, but statistical uncertainty in these estimates
cannot rule out the former version.
The paper is organized as follows. Section Idescribes how I measure inflation
variance ratios and discusses the data used to construct shocks to inflation
expectations. Section II documents the low level of the ratio in the data. Section
III discusses volatilities of components of yield shocks in various macro-finance
equilibrium models. Section IV attempts to determine the relative roles of news
about expected future short rates and expected future returns. An Internet
Appendix, available in the online version of the article on the Journal of Finance
website, contains detailed discussions of various issues.
I. Inflation Variance Ratios
“Inflation news” is not a clear-cut concept—there is no unique or best way to
measure how shocks associated with an inflation process affect nominal bond
yields. The New Keynesian model examined by Rudebusch and Swanson (2012;
hereafter R/S) helps illustrate the ambiguity. In the model, there are no exoge-
nous shocks to inflation. Thus, in a narrow sense, there is no inflation news.
However, shocks to productivity, monetary policy, and government spending
each affect the paths of expected inflation, real rates, and nominal bond risk
premia. Thus, in a broad sense, all news is inflation news, as every shock con-
veys information about expected future inflation. Models in which a monetary
authority follows a Taylor rule typically have the same property. Outside the
special cases, a shock to any variable that appears in the Taylor rule affects
both yields and expected future inflation.
Rather than adopt a specific model’s interpretation of inflation shocks, in
this paper I measure the magnitude of inflation news using an accounting
approach that has its roots in the dividend/price decomposition of Campbell
and Shiller (1988), as extended to returns by Campbell (1991). The measure
is straightforward to estimate with available data. Any dynamic model of both
inflation and bond yields—a class of which includes a wide variety of dynamic
macro models—implies a value of a bond’s inflation variance ratio.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT