ETF Competition and Market Quality

AuthorRyan L. Davis,Travis Box,Kathleen P. Fuller
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12246
Published date01 September 2019
Date01 September 2019
ETF Competition and Market Quality
Travis Box, Ryan L. Davis, and Kathleen P. Fuller
This paper examines competition between exchange tradedfunds (ETFs) that hold nearly identical
portfolios of securities. We provide evidence that incumbent-fund liquidity is negatively affected
when a new ETF is added to an asset class. The degradation in liquidity is even more severe
whenever both funds follow the same benchmark.We also document a decline in primary-market
activity for the incumbent ETFs after the arrival of new competitors. Furthermore, increasingthe
number of funds in an asset class does not put downwardpressure on fund management fees. Thus,
the deterioration in market quality may not be offset by decreasingcosts of fund ownership.
Exchange traded funds (ETFs) provide access to a large diversified portfolio of securities that
can easily be traded throughout the day. From 1997 to 2017, the aggregate total net assets (TNA) of
passively managed,long-only ETFs listed in the United States has grown from $2.2 billion to just
under $3 trillion, whereas the total number of funds has expanded from 18 to 1,204. As new ETFs
have poured into the marketplace, the likelihood that multiple funds compete within the same
asset class has risen considerably. Our paper considers how the degree of competition between
passively managed ETFs affects their secondary-market liquidity, primary-market activity, and
the management fees paid by investors.
When multiple ETFs track a similar benchmark, their intrinsic values derive from nearly
identical portfolios of underlying assets. If the degree of substitutability between competing funds
is high, ETF sponsors may lower management fees to lure market share away from their rivals.
Although investors should respond positivelyto any potential decline in expenses, the addition of
a new ETF to an asset class may also reduce the share of secondary-market order flow to each of
the incumbent funds. Barclay and Hendershott (2004) and Hendershott and Jones (2005) provide
evidence that order flow fragmentation maylead to wider bid-ask spreads and lower overall depth.
Similarly, Pagano (1989) argues that order flow consolidation leads to an improvement in the
liquidity of a market. Thus, if the addition of a new fund splits trading between similar ETFs,
incumbent funds may experience a reduction in liquidity, whereby market participants experience
wider bid-ask spreads and lower overall depth.1Conversely, several empirical studies have found
improvements in liquidity after markets become more fragmented (e.g., Bessembinder, 2003b;
We appreciate the helpful comments of Bing Han (Editor), an anonymous referee, Michael Goldstein, Marc Lipson,
Andrew Lynch, Robert Van Ness and David Stowe, as well as seminar participants at Auburn University, University of
Alabama at Birmingham, the 2016 Magnolia Conference,the 2016 Southern Finance Association Annual Meetings, and
the 2017 Midwest Finance Association Annual Meetings.
Travis Boxis an Assistant Professor of Finance in the College of Business at Clemson University, SC and was formerly
an Assistant Professor of Finance in the College of Business at the University of Mississippi in University, MS. Ryan
Davis is an Assistant Professor of Financein the Collat School of Business at the University of Alabama at Birmingham
in Birmingham, AL. Kathleen Fuller is an Associate Professor of Financein the College of Business at the University of
Mississippi in University, MS.
1Malamud (2016) suggests that the introduction of new ETFs may lead to a decrease in liquidity for existing ETFs
through a demand substitution effect. Cherkes, Sagi, and Stanton (2009) develop a model that shows the creation of a
new closed-end fund reduces both the demand in and the liquidity benefit provided by other funds within that particular
sector. In addition, Corwin and Coughenour (2008) find that when New York Stock Exchange specialists allocate their
attention to stocks with increased trading activity,the liquidity of the other stocks in their por tfolio decreases. Similarly,
Financial Management Fall 2019 pages 873 – 916
874 Financial Management rFall 2019
Boehmer and Boehmer, 2003; O’Hara and Ye, 2011). In addition, Malamud (2016) suggests that
the introduction of new ETFs may also improve liquidity in the underlying securities, which in
turn could boost the secondary-market liquidity of existing ETFs.
Our results, based on a sample of 1,275 ETFs from 1997 to 2017, indicate that the entry of a new
competitor increases intraday effective spreads for the incumbent funds in the same asset class
by 0.49 basis points relative to ETFs with similar levelsof trading volume, authorized participant
activity, stock returns, and fund flows.2Whenever the entrant also tracks the same benchmark as
the incumbent fund, the decline in secondary-market liquidity for the incumbent funds becomes
even more extreme, with effective spreads widening by 9.05 basis points relative to funds with
similar characteristics. Following Glosten (1987), wedecompose effective spreads into a realized
spread component and a price impact component to determine whether the increase in transaction
costs leads to greater revenue for liquidity providers, greater losses for liquidity demanders due
to adverse selection, or both. Although our results indicate that adverse selection can explain
some of the losses experienced by liquidity demanders, an increase in the proportion of surplus
captured by liquidity providers accounts for most of the widening observed in effective spreads.
Unlike common stocks, ETFs have an open-ended structure via the share creation and redemp-
tion process that facilitates arbitrage between the fund and its underlying portfolio of securities.3
Thus, the primary market for ETFs acts as an additional layer of liquidity that allows large insti-
tutional investors to trade ETFs in the primary market by exchanging the underlyingpor tfolio for
new ETF shares, or in the secondary market by exchanging cash for the ETF, depending on where
trading costs are lower. For a more complete picture of the effects of competition on liquidity,
we use the frequency with which ETF shares are created or redeemed to capture primary-market
liquidity. Specifically, we use the coefficient of variation for each fund’s shares outstanding to
approximate the level of activity in the primary market for a particular ETF. Although we observe
only minor changes in the volatility of shares outstanding following the entry of a competing
fund into an asset class, we find a significant reduction in the coeffi cient of variation for shares
outstanding when the entrant also follows the same benchmark. Thus, the introduction of a nearly
perfect substitute affects both the primary and secondary market for shares of the incumbent funds.
Notwithstanding higher secondary-market transaction costs, ETF investors could still benefit
from the arrival of a new fund into an asset class if incumbent funds respond by lowering
management fees. For a comprehensive view of investor expenses over time, we calculate the
value-weighted average of fund management fees during each year of our sample for all major
investment types. Despite the dramatic increase in aggregate TNA, along with a growingnumber
of categories with competing funds, a typical ETF investor in 2017 faces roughly the same value-
weighted management fees as they did in 1997.4Narrowing our focus to individual funds, we
analyze the frequency of yearly fee changes and find that investor expenses are unchanged from
in our setting, ETF investor attention maybe redirected by the arrival of new ETFs to a particular area causing the trading
environments of incumbent ETFs to deteriorate.
2Our sample includes 1,275 ETFs across all years but only 1,204 in 2017.
3Should an ETF trade at a premium, for example, a specially designated institutional investor known as an authorized
participant (AP) could purchase the underlying securities, exchange the portfolio for new ETF shares from the fund
sponsor, and then sell the newlycreated shares on the secondar y market.In practice, an AP could simultaneously buy the
underlying shares and short the ETF.At the end of the trading day, the AP would exchange the underlying portfolio for
ETF shares and then close the short ETF position.
4Our results appear to contradict the reporting of the popular press. Barron’s (“ETF Fee Wars Ramp Up,” November
21, 2015) and the Wall Street Journal (“A New Low-Cost Leader among Stock ETFs,” November 10, 2015) reported
that BlackRock, the largest provider of ETFs, cut management fees by more than half in one of their ETFs. Almost
immediately,Charles Schwab cut fees for their competing ETF. Box, Davis, and Fuller (2018) examine this high-profile
fee war and conclude that this case is not representative of the overall ETF industry and that the fees associated with
Box, et al. rETF Competition and Market Quality 875
the previous year across 67.0% of the observations in our sample. For ETFs in categories that
experience an increase in competition, we find that incumbent funds maintain their fees while
entrants charge higher fees during the following year. Ultimately, we find no evidence that fund
sponsors consistently lower fees in the face of competition. Therefore, the reported increase in
effective spreads does not appear to be offset by a decrease in the cost of ETF ownership.
A novelty of our study is that we examine liquidity in a context that is nearly devoid of
competition between market centers. Unlike previous studies that consider competition between
exchanges for order flow in the same securities (e.g., McInish and Wood, 1992; Bessembinder,
2003b; Boehmer and Boehmer, 2003; O’Hara and Ye, 2011), our analysis is unique because
we focus on the addition of new securities that happen to be identical in nearly every way.
In addition, we believe that our study makes two important contributions to the existing ETF
literature. First, we highlight a previously unknown consequence of the ETF industry’s growth
whereby incumbent-fund liquidity decreases after new ETFs enter the market. Second, despite
recent headlines in the popular press and the findings of comparable studies in the mutual fund
literature, we find little evidence that ETF sponsors engage in price competition by reducing
management fees.
I. Conceptual Underpinnings
A. ETFs, the Financial System, and the Market Quality of Underlying Securities
A variety of researchers and regulators have raised specific concerns about the pricing and
trading of these investment vehicles. Chief among these concerns is that ETFs may contribute to
instability when markets are most vulnerable. Ramaswamy (2011) suggests that the complexity
of some ETFs may increase systematic risks in the financial system. Likewise, the Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC) highlighted the role of ETFs in its official reviews of the May 6,
2010, Flash Crash and the August 24, 2015, stock market plunge.5,6 Others have argued, however,
that such associations between financial market stability and the rise of ETFs may be somewhat
speculative. Madhavan and Sobczyk (2015) show that large net asset value discounts observed in
bond ETFs during periods of stress, such as the financial crisis, reflect efficient pricing, and that
ETFs are not a source of additional volatility or systematic risk.
The literature also cautions that the intraday liquidity of ETFs might attract short-term traders
who introduce noise into the underlying security prices through the arbitrage of fund shares.
Broman and Shum (2016) document that there is, in fact, precisely this type of liquidity clientele
among institutional investors. Malamud (2016) introduces a theoretical model that demonstrates
how the creation and redemption mechanism of ETF shares serves as a shock propagation channel
that allows temporary demand shocks to leave an enduring impact on constituent security prices.
Ben-David, Franzoni, and Moussawi (2018) observe that ETFs increase the nonfundamental
volatility of the securities in their, and Da and Shive(2018) f ind that ETF ownership is associated
with higher realizations of comovement between their underlying holdings. For fixed-income
ETFs, Dannhauser (2017) shows that the liquidity of constituent securities falls as ETF ownership
most funds “are being held steady or even climbing” (“Feeson Mutual Funds and ETFs Tumble toward Zero,” Wall Street
Journal, January 26, 2016).
5“Findings Regarding Market Events of May 6, 2010,” prepared by the staffs of the Commodity Futures Trading
Commission (CFTC) and SEC, available at: https://www.sec.gov/news/studies/2010/marketevents-report.pdf.
6“Equity Market Volatility on August 24, 2015,” prepared by the staff of the SEC, available at: https://www.sec.gov/
marketstructure/research/equity_market_volatility.pdf.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT