Equilibrium Principal‐Agent Contracts: Competition and R&D Incentives

Published date01 September 2013
AuthorMichela Cella,Federico Etro
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12021
Date01 September 2013
Equilibrium Principal-Agent Contracts:
Competition and R&D Incentives
FEDERICO ETRO
University of Venice
Ca’ Foscari
federicoetro@yahoo.it
MICHELA CELLA
University of Milan
Bicocca
michela.cella@unimib.it
We analyze competition between firms engaged in R&D activities and market competition to
study the choice of the incentive contracts for managers with hidden productivity. Oligopolistic
screening requires extra effort/investment from the most productive managers: under additional
assumptions on the hazard rate of the distribution of types we obtain no distortion in the middle
rather than at the top. The equilibrium contracts are characterized by effort differentials between
(any) two types always increasing with the number of firms, suggesting a positive relation
between competition and high-powered incentives. An inverted U curve between competition
and absolute investments can emerge for the most productive managers.
1. Introduction
A wide literature on contract theory has described how asymmetric information shapes
the optimal contracts between a principal and an agent with private information. For
instance, when the agent is the manager of a monopolistic firm and has private infor-
mation on the productivity of effort, the optimal contract requires the first best effort for
the most productive type and a downward distortion of effort for all the less productive
types, with effort differentials associated with wage differentials in a way that insures
incentive compatibility (see Stiglitz, 1977 or Baron and Myerson, 1982). However,when a
firm is not a monopolist, but competes in the market with other firms, we can expect that
the optimal contracts are affected by competition and the competitive prices are affected
by the contracts implemented by all the firms. Although the analysis of equilibrium
principal–agent contracts has been studied in models with perfect competition [see Roth-
schild and Stiglitz (1976), or more recently, Bisin and Gottardi (2006) and Pouyet et al.
(2008)], there is limited work for the general case of imperfect competition. The notable
exception of Martimort (1996) examines equilibrium contracts in a duopoly where the
types of managers of the firms are perfectly correlated: this is a reasonable assumption
in the presence of common aggregate shocks, but not in the presence of firm-specific
shocks or asymmetric information on the productivity of the managers. We augment
principal–agent models between firms competing in the market and their managers
We are grateful to Hongbin Cai, Jacques Cremer, Martin Cripps, Jeoren Hinloopen, Eugen Kovac, Daniel
Kr¨
ahmer, Matthias Kr¨
akel, Konrad Mierendorff, Piergiovanna Natale, Patrick Rey, Urs Schweizer, and par-
ticipants at seminars at the Peking University, University of Bonn, University of Amsterdam, and Cresse
conference in Crete for discussions on the topic.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 3, Fall 2013, 488–512
Competition and R&D Incentives 489
with idiosyncratic and uncorrelated shocks that give raise to equilibrium contracts that
differ from those offered by a monopolistic firm. The aim is to investigate how entry in
a market affects the equilibrium contracts and, in turn, how these contracts affect the
endogenous market structure.
We consider firms that in a first stage choose contracts for their managers and in
a second stage compete in the market. Each contract provides incentives to undertake
R&D activities that reduce the marginal cost. At the time of competing `
alaCournot in
the last stage, the contracts or the cost-reducing activity become observable in our base-
line model. The interesting interaction occurs at the initial contractual stage between
the firms and their managers. The managers are ex ante homogenous but, after being
matched with a firm, they differ in their productivities, which are identically and inde-
pendently distributed. Weconsider as a benchmark case the one in which productivities
can be observed by the firm’s owner (but not by the rival), and then we consider the
more realistic situation in which each productivity level is private information to each
manager. The contracts are expressed in terms of effort/wage schedules. Our focus is
on Bayesian Nash competition in contracts: these are chosen simultaneously, taking as
given the contracts offered by the other firms.
The equilibrium principal–agent contracts require extra effort from the most pro-
ductive managers compared to the equilibrium contracts emerging with symmetric
information. This deviation from the traditional property of “no distortion at the top”
emerges because of the strategic interactions between contracts for different types (due
to strategic substitutability between efforts). In particular, the fact that all the competi-
tors commit to distort downward the effort of their inefficient managers increases the
marginal profitability of the effort of an efficient manager (likely to compete with in-
efficient ones), and vice versa. This enhances the polarization of the efforts required
from different managers. Under additional assumptions on the hazard rate of the dis-
tribution of types (which must be positive enough) we actually obtain “no distortion
in the middle”: all the best (worst) types exert more (less) effort than under symmetric
information.
Our main result on the relation between competition and incentives is the follow-
ing: the effort differential between (any) two types of managers is always increasing in
the number of firms, which may suggest a positive relation between competition and
high-powered incentive schemes. Loosely speaking, competition enhances meritocracy:
when the number of firms increases, each firm tends to differentiate more its contracts
(i.e., spend relatively more on wages for the best managers), requiring a relativelyhigher
effort from an efficient manager because this can lead to larger gains against less effi-
cient rivals. Also the absolute effort levels can increase with the number of firms, but
only for the most efficient managers: moreover, we show that in such a case an inverted
U curve between competition and absolute investment in cost-reducing activities can
emerge.
A wide industrial organization literature, started by Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980),
Tan do n (1984), and Sutton (1991) and generalized in recent work by Vives (2008), has
studied the impact of competition on deterministic cost-reduction activities, showing
that an increase in the number of homogenous firms tends to reduce production, profits,
and investment of each firm. Our model generalizes this framework with heterogeneity
and uncertainty in firms’ productivity and also asymmetric information between firms’
owners and their managers engaged in the cost-reducing activities. Following the cited
literature, we also consider the case of endogenous market structures, that emphasizes
a positive relation between market size and relative (and possibly absolute) measures of

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT