Embracing the Second Best? Synchronization of Reform Speeds, Excess High Discretion Slack, and Performance of Transition Economy Firms

Published date01 May 2014
Date01 May 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.2042-5805.2014.1075.x
EMBRACING THE SECOND BEST?
SYNCHRONIZATION OF REFORM SPEEDS, EXCESS
HIGH DISCRETION SLACK, AND PERFORMANCE OF
TRANSITION ECONOMY FIRMS
ELITSA R. BANALIEVA*
International Business & Strategy Group, D’Amore-McKim School of
Business, Northeastern University, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.
I extend the institution-based view by adopting a horse race perspective on pro-market reforms.
Specifically, I study how the synchronizationof reform speeds (the extent of coordination across
a country’s reform rates of implementation) affects the performance of transition economy
firms. I suggest that synchronized faster reforms (the horse race) yield mutually reinforcing and
complementary benefits that enhance firm performance. Additionally, I propose that greater
excess high discretion slack (the degree of internally generated excess liquidity a firm has after
external demands on the firm’s financial resources are met) further strengthens this positive
relationship because it allows firms to pursue aggressively the market opportunities that
proliferate in the rapidly transforming economy. Tests on a sample of 211 firms from 14
transition economies during 1991 to 2009 support this framework. Copyright © 2014 Strategic
Management Society.
INTRODUCTION
One cannot cross an abyss in two jumps.
David Lloyd-George, British Prime Minister
(Dajani, 2005: 113)
The fall of communism in the early 1990s trig-
gered a formidable institution-building effort across
many countries. To transition from their centrally
planned heritage to a free enterprise system, for-
merly communist countries had to embark on estab-
lishing market-based institutions from scratch
(Bevan, Estrin, and Meyer, 2004; Kriauciunas and
Kale, 2006). To achieve this, the transition econo-
mies adopted pro-market reforms: policies designed
to enhance market principles in key areas like enter-
prise restructuring, trade and financial liberalization,
and infrastructure development (Bevan et al., 2004;
EBRD, 2010). Consequently, some countries gal-
loped into a horse race of ‘radial’ reforms (i.e.,
‘achieving proportional reductions in all distortions
at the same time,’ Braga de Macedo and Martins,
2008: 142), and proceeded by implementing simul-
taneous faster (i.e., synchronized faster) or gradual
(i.e., synchronized slower) reforms.1Yet other coun-
tries implemented some reforms much faster (i.e.,
asynchronized faster) or much slower (i.e.,
asynchronized slower) than the rest of the reforms.
These different rates of transition have been
debated. First, economists have questioned whether
a rapid (shock therapy) or gradual speed of reform is
Keywords: institution-based view; synchronization of reform
speeds; excess high discretion slack; performance; transition
economy firms
*Correspondence to: Elitsa R. Banalieva, International
Business & Strategy Group, D’Amore-McKim School of
Business, Northeastern University, Boston, MA 02115-5000,
U.S.A. E-mail: e.banalieva@neu.edu
1For greater clarity of presentation, I use ‘reforms’ and ‘pro-
market reforms’ interchangeably.
Global Strategy Journal
Global Strat. J., 4: 104–126 (2014)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1111/j.2042-5805.2014.1075.x
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society
better for countries. Some have argued that shock
therapy prevents reform reversals and allows for a
big enough jump over the institutional abyss
(Havrylyshyn, 2007; Lipton and Sachs, 1990).
Others have countered that gradual reforms secure a
longer adjustment period (Godoy and Stiglitz, 2007;
Murrell, 1992). Second, economists have also
debated if different scopes of reforms (i.e., the extent
of implementation of free market principles in a
country in a given year) are complementary such that
‘the return of doing one reform is enhanced when
other reforms are in place’ too (Braga de Macedo
and Martins, 2008: 142). While some have noted that
countries can reach a ‘first best’ outcome from pur-
suing such a coordinated strategy of radial shock
therapy throughout the economy (Braga de Macedo
and Martins, 2008; Chang, Kaltani, and Loayza,
2009; Gates, Milgrom, and Roberts, 1996; Rocha,
2009), others have suggested that countries can
embrace the ‘second best’ outcome of coordinated
gradual reforms if the first best outcome is unreach-
able (Foster and Sonnenschein, 1970; McKinnon,
1993).
While these debates have persisted at the country-
level, strategy research has duly noted that ‘improv-
ing knowledge about firm behavior in these
[transition economy] countries has become more
important both for theory and practice’ (Kriauciunas
and Kale, 2006: 661). How the synchronization of
reform speeds (extent of coordination across a coun-
try’s reform rates of implementation since start of
transition) affects firm performance remains
underexplored in extant literature (Gates et al.,
1996). The few existing empirical firm-level studies
have focused on reform scope (Chari and David,
2012; Cuervo-Cazurra and Dau, 2009; Park, Li, and
Tse, 2006), suggesting it can increase firm perfor-
mance due to improved incentive mechanisms
(Cuervo-Cazurra and Dau, 2009; Park et al., 2006)
or hurt the persistence of superior profits due to
increased competition (Chari and David, 2012).
The scope of reforms offers a snapshot of a coun-
try’s institutions, as it does not capture the extent of
coordination across the reform rates of implementa-
tion (i.e., the synchronization of reform speeds). In
line with recent management research (e.g., Jones
and Coviello, 2005), I suggest that the synchroniza-
tion of reform speeds provides a useful evolutionary
understanding of how pro-market reforms since the
start of transition have affected the performance of
firms continuing their existence under the new
market reality. In so doing, this article addresses an
important call in the literature, noting that time is
‘seldom positioned as a primary conceptual dimen-
sion to which explicit behavior may be tagged and
understood’ (Jones and Coviello, 2005: 288).
Accordingly, the central research question of this
article is: how the synchronization of reform speeds
affects the performance of transition economy firms
that have continued existing under the new market
reality. In analyzing this question, I extend the
institution-based view of the firm (Meyer et al.,
2009; Peng, Wang, and Jiang, 2008) by adopting a
horse race perspective of the pro-market reforms in a
country’s reform portfolio. Furthermore, while the
institution-based view has emphasized that institu-
tions matter, it has paid less attention to how transi-
tion economy firms adapt to their changing
institutional environments. In fact, ‘interactions
between national economic institutions and enter-
prise level organizational strategies are still under-
researched’ (Bevan et al., 2004: 44). Hence, I also
study how these firms adapt to the synchronization
of reform speeds through a specific mechanism: i.e.,
by balancing the internal supply of financial
resources with the external demand on these
resources, which I refer to as excess high discretion
slack.
SYNCHRONIZATION OF REFORM
SPEEDS AND PERFORMANCE OF
TRANSITION ECONOMY FIRMS
Prior research on the institution-based view of
the firm
The institution-based view has emphasized that
institutions matter for firms’ strategies (North, 1990;
Peng et al., 2008). The institution-based view
becomes particularly relevant in transition econo-
mies, as they were once under government control
and the state had to establish market-based institu-
tions from scratch. Pro-market reforms are the
mechanism through which countries have been
accomplishing this institutional transition to a free
enterprise system. Specifically, pro-market reforms
are policies that promote ‘macroeconomic stability,
market economy, and outward orientation’
(Williamson and Haggard, 1994: 529). They aim to
reduce the active involvement of the state in the
economy and open the country to market-based
supply and demand mechanisms (Williamson,
1990).
Synchronization of Reform Speeds 105
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society Global Strat. J., 4: 104–126 (2014)
DOI: 10.1111/j.2042-5805.2014.1075.x

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT