Economizing and strategizing: How coalitions and transaction costs shape value creation and appropriation

AuthorKirsten Foss,Christian G. Asmussen,Peter G. Klein,Nicolai J. Foss
Date01 February 2021
Published date01 February 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3227
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Economizing and strategizing: How coalitions
and transaction costs shape value creation and
appropriation
Christian G. Asmussen
1,2
| Kirsten Foss
3
| Nicolai J. Foss
2,3
|
Peter G. Klein
3,4
1
King's Business School, King's College
London, London, UK
2
Department of Strategy and Innovation,
Copenhagen Business School,
Frederiksberg, Denmark
3
Department of Strategy and
Management, Norwegian School of
Economics, Bergen, Norway
4
Department of Entrepreneurship, Baylor
University, Waco, Texas
Correspondence
Nicolai J. Foss, Department of Strategy
and Management, Copenhagen Business
School, Frederiksberg, Denmark;
Department of Strategy and Innovation,
Norwegian School of Economics, Bergen,
Norway.
Email: njf.si@cbs.dk
Abstract
Research summary: Research has examined how
economizingand strategizingmechanisms interact in
driving competitive outcomes, but the role of coalitions in
this process has received little attention. Coalitions are
formed to create more value (i.e., economizing) and to
strengthen competitive positions (i.e., strategizing). Based
on a formal coalitional model, we derive several unintuitive
results. We show that economizing actions may backfire
because creating more value may lead other players to
strategize more aggressively, offsetting the additional value
creation. Moreover, creating countervailing powerthat is,
building a coalition against players with significant power
such as monopolistsnot only allows the coalition to
appropriate more value, but may also benefit the powerful
trading partner by reducing competition among the coali-
tion members. Coalition-formation can hurt coalitions
members by reducing economizing investments.
Managerial summary: Managers typically seek com-
petitive advantage either by improving efficiency
(by having unique resources, lowering costs, or improv-
ing managerial practices) or by trying to obtain stron-
ger bargaining positions against their buyers or
suppliers. We show that these two approaches interact in
surprising ways. For example, efficiency improvements cre-
ate more opportunity for profit, but also give trading
Received: 19 February 2018 Revised: 8 July 2020 Accepted: 29 July 2020 Published on: 15 September 2020
DOI: 10.1002/smj.3227
Strat Mgmt J. 2021;42:413434. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/smj © 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 413
partners stronger incentives to bargain for a share of that
profit. At the same time, small buyers or sellers can band
together into clubs or cooperatives to get better deals from a
powerful trading partner, thereby restraining competition
among themselves. However, large firms can try to prevent
such coalitions from forming by pursuing vertical integra-
tion of potential coalition members. We explore a variety of
bargaining situations and show that the ability to encourage
or thwart coalition formation is an important
managerial tool.
KEYWORDS
bargaining, cooperative games, economizing, strategizing,
transaction costs
1|INTRODUCTION
The strategy literature emphasizes two distinct paths to superior firm performance: a position-
ing approach in which firms make their own markets less competitive by strategizing relative to
rivals, and an efficiency approach that emphasizes a firm's productive assets, relationships, and
managerial practices as the main sources of competitive advantage (e.g., Williamson, 1991,
p. 75; Peteraf & Barney, 2003, p. 320). This distinction is often framed as a contest between
strategizingand economizingviews (Williamson, 1991). Based on industrial economics
(Bain, 1959; Tirole, 1988), strategizing theories highlight market power: Firms achieve supra-
normal profits by creating and sustaining entry barriers, preventing rivals from competing these
profits away (Porter, 1980, 1981). By contrast, economizing theories emphasize efficiency as the
source of competitive advantage (Barney, 1991; Williamson, 1985). The two approaches offer
distinct mechanisms that generate sustained heterogeneity in competitive outcomes (e.g., see
Williamson, 1991, p. 76; Peteraf & Barney, 2003, pp. 320321).
However, scholars increasingly recognize that the mechanisms underlying these views are
intertwined (Foss & Foss, 2005; Mahoney & Qian, 2013), and several models examine these
links in detail. Thus, Nickerson and van den Berg (1999) investigate assets and organization
choices in a Cournot setting (see also Nickerson, Hamilton, & Wada, 2001). Foss and Foss (2005)
argue that in the presence of transaction costs, economizing and strategizing cannot in general
be separated, as transaction costs make it costly to protect assets and rent streams against other
parties' efforts to strategize (i.e., to capture value associated with those assets or rent streams,
see also Foss, Foss, & Klein, 2018). Makadok (2010) builds a model in which competitive advan-
tage (i.e., economizing) and rivalry restraint (i.e., strategizing) have a negative interaction effect
on profit. Bel (2018) derives results from the resource-based and positioning views as special
cases within an overarching framework based on property rights theory (Hart, 1995). Makadok
and Ross (2018) examine the adverse competitor replacementthat may happen when a supe-
rior incumbent gets stronger, drives a weaker rival from the market, but thereby invites a stron-
ger rival to enter in its place.
414 ASMUSSEN ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT