Economic Expert Testimony

Pages231-268
231
CHAPTER VIII
ECONOMIC EXPERT TESTIMONY
Economists often play a role in explaining some of the evidence in
both civil and criminal antitrust conspiracy cases. This Chapter examines
in greater depth the legal and practical considerations of using economists
effectively in attempting to prove or disprove conspiracy. It starts with a
description of some of the theoretical underpinnings of economic analysis
and their limitations. A discussion of how economists analyze market
conditions that may be conducive to collusion follows. The chapter then
turns to a review of empirical tools economists employ to inform their
analyses of market conditions. Finally, the chapter reviews the legal
standards of admissibility of expert economic testimony that have been
applied in the antitrust conspiracy context.
A. The Use of Economic Evidence to Support or Detract from an
Inference of Conspiracy
In antitrust conspiracy cases where there has not been a guilty plea by
one or more defendants, or where a guilty plea is restrictive compared to
the potential scope of the conspiracy, the testimony of an expert economist
can be important in helping to support or refute liability. An expert
economist can aid the court and/or trier of fact in understanding the
economic significance of evidence introduced in the case through applying
economic reasoning to explain some of the evidence (and often
incorporating a range of peer-reviewed papers to support that reasoning).1
While horizontal price fixing and some other forms of conspiracy are
per se antitrust violations, “a Section 1 plaintiff’s offer of co nspiracy
evidence must tend to rule out the possibility that the defendants were
acting independently” to survive summary judgment or to support a civil
1. See 2 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANT ITRUST LAW: AN
ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINC IPLES AN D THEIR APPLICATION, ¶ 309a (4th
ed. 2014); The Sedona Conference Working Group on the Role of
Economics in Antitrust Law, Commentary on the Role of Economics in
Antitrust Law, 7 SEDONA CONF. J. 69, 123-26 (2006).
232 Proof of Conspiracy Under Federal Antitrust Laws
jury verdict.2 In cases resting on circumstantial or ambiguous evidence of
conspiracy, a plaintiff “must show that the inference of conspiracy is
reasonable in light of the competing inferences of independent action or
collusive action that could not have harmed respondents.”3
Defendants are not entitled to summary judgment or directed verdict
“merely by showing that there is a plausible explanation for their conduct;
rather, the focus must remain on the evidence proffered by the plaintiff
and whether that evidence tends to exclude the possibility that [the
defendants] were acting independently.”4 Appropriately grounded in the
facts of the case, economic analysis can often provide insight into this
question.5
Because economic theory suggests that mere parallel pricing or other
parallel practices can be the result of independent behavior based on
common perceptions of market conditions or expected (but not agreed
upon) responses from competitors, the law has developed to require the
plaintiff to identify certain types of evidence or indicators that support an
inference of agreement, often called “plus factors.”6 The evidence put
forth by plaintiffs typically falls into two categories: (1) evidence
regarding the behavior of the defendants (e.g., communications or
meetings between the defendants or sharing of information); and (2)
evidence regarding the conduciveness of the relevant market to
conspiracy.7
2. Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S.544, 554 (2007).
3. Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588
(1986).
4. Intervest, Inc. v. Bl oomberg, L.P., 340 F.3 d 144, 160 (3d Cir. 2003)
(quoting Rossi v. Standard Roofing, 156 F.3d 452, 466 (3d Cir. 1998)
(internal quotations omitted)).
5. For more on the appropriate uses and limitations on expert economic
testimony as evidence on the question of agreement, see 2 AREEDA &
HOVENKAMP, supra note 1, 309c (4th ed. 2014); Herbert Hovenkamp,
Economic Experts in Antitrust Cases, in 5 MOD. SCI. EVID. § 44:12 (David
L. Faigman et al., eds., 2015-16 ed.); The Sedona Conference Working
Group on the Role of Economics in Antitrust Law, Chapter VI. Economics
and Proof of Concerted Action, 6 SEDONA CONF. J. 69 (2005).
6. William E. Kovacic et al., Plus Factors and Agreement in Antitrust Law,
110 MICH. L. REV. 393, 405-06 (2011). See Chapter III for a more
comprehensive discussion of “plus factors.”
7. See Gregory J. Werden, Economic Evidence on the Existence of Collusion:
Reconciling Antitrust Law with Oligopoly Theory, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 719,
791 n.337 (2004) (“Economic literature on the structural characteristics of
Economic Expert Testimony 233
With respect to the latter category of evidence, economic principles
and knowledge can be used to evaluate the characteristics of the market at
issue, and, in particular, whether the nature and structure of transactions,
products, and firms in the particular market make successful collusion
more or less likely. In addition, economists can assess whether observed
market outcomes are consistent with independent action or, conversely,
support an inference that market actors have been colluding, tacitly or
explicitly.8
B. The Distinction Between Tacit Collusion and Explicit Collusion
As explained in Chapter VII, it is important to note that the economic
concept of collusion is not necessarily consistent with the legal concept of
agreement.9 Firms in an oligopolistic industry often recognize their mutual
interdependence over time. What economists sometimes call “tacit”
collusion can arise when firms recognize their shared interests in higher
prices over a longer time horizon, anticipate their rivals’ actions by
observing each other’s market behavior, and take actions that are
consistent with these shared interests.10 When all firms in the industry
industries in which conspiracies were prosecuted criminally indicates that
conspiracies have occurred despite unfavorable conditions.”).
8. See, e.g., In re Chocolate Confectionary Antitrust Litig., 801 F.3d 383, 399
(3d Cir. 2015); In re High Fructose Corn Syrup Ant itrust Litig., 295 F.3d
651, 655 (7th Cir. 2002).
9. See Chapter VII.2.d, supra (quoting Professor Hovenkamp’s stateme nt that
“the discipline of economics ha[s] no competence to determine whether
parallel behavior among independent actors amount[s] to a legal
‘agreement’” (quotation marks omitted)); see also Robert H. Porter & J.
Douglas Zona, Collusion in Economics, in ISSUES IN COMPE TITION LAW
AND POLICY 1069, 1071 (Wayne Dale ed., 2008) (“Under interdependent
oligopoly, there need be no agreement. Under consciously parallel or
tacitly collusive behavior, an agreement (if any) is tacit. Under explicit
collusion, there is a n actual agreeme nt and some common understanding.
As a matter of economics, it is difficult and perhaps impossible to
distinguish between these types of behavior on the bases of outcomes
alone.”).
10. See Edward Green et al., Tacit Collusion in Oligopoly, in OXFORD
HANDBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL ANTITRUST ECONOMICS, at 464-97
(2015); 6 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW:
AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION,
1410b (3d ed. 2010); DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF,
MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 127 (4th ed. 2005).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT