Dynamics in a Mature Industry: Entry, Exit, and Growth of Big‐Box Grocery Retailers

Published date01 March 2015
AuthorDaniel Hanner,Loren K. Smith,Luke M. Olson,Daniel Hosken
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12087
Date01 March 2015
Dynamics in a Mature Industry: Entry, Exit, and
Growth of Big-Box Grocery Retailers
DANIEL HANNER
U.S. Federal Trade Commission
600 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20580
dhanner@ftc.gov
DANIEL HOSKEN
U.S. Federal Trade Commission
600 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20580
dhosken@ftc.gov
LUKE M. OLSON
U.S. Federal Trade Commission
600 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20580
lolson@ftc.gov
LOREN K. SMITH
Compass Lexecon
1101 K Street NW
Washington, DC 20005
LSmith@CompassLexecon.com
This paper measures market dynamics within the U.S. grocery industry (defined as supermarket,
supercenter,and club retailers). We find that despite being a mature industry, the groceryindustry
is remarkably dynamic. Each year retailers open or close roughly 7% of U.S. stores. We also find
significant changes in the size of firms’ operations within markets over time. These changes in
relative size are largely the result of expansion or contraction by incumbents rather than the
result of firm entry or exit. In fact, entry and exit are quite rare, except by small firms. Moreover,
only in small markets do new entrants gain substantial market share.
1. Introduction
Entry and exit by firms play an important role in generating economic growth and
are key elements of the competitive process in the long run. Foster et al. (2006), for
example, find that virtually all of the labor productivity growth in the retail sector in
the 1990s was the result of entry and expansion by high productivity firms and the
exit of less productive firms. What is less clear is when entry and exit play an im-
portant role in disciplining markets in the intermediate run—2 to 5 years—which is
We thank Christopher Adams for his help in getting this project started and Joseph Farrell, David Schmidt,
Christopher Taylor, Steven Tenn, Matthew Weinberg, Nathan Wilson, and two anonymous referees for com-
ments. The views expressed in this paper arethose of the authors and do not represent those of the U.S. Federal
Trade Commission or any individual Commissioner.
Published 2015. This article is a U.S. Government work and is in the public domain in the USA.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 1, Spring 2015, 22–46
Big-Box Grocery Retailers 23
the relevant time period for antitrust authorities in developing an effective competi-
tion policy. The U.S. government’s primary policy document describing merger pol-
icy, the 2010 Department of Justice (DOJ)/Federal Trade Commission (FTC) Horizontal
Merger Guidelines, describes the conditions under which entry (or the threat of entry) can
cause seemingly anticompetitive mergers to be permissible.1In particular,the Guidelines
note that, “the prospect of entry into the relevant market will alleviate concerns about
adverse competitive effects only if such entry will deter or counteract any competitive
effects of concern so the merger will not substantially harm customers.” Hence, even
if merger induced entry would eventually eliminate competitive harm, that merger is
still illegal if customers suffer substantial harm as the market moves back toward a
competitive equilibrium.
Determining whether entry would be easy and sufficient to replace the loss of
competition resulting from a merger has proven difficult. Werden and Froeb (1998), for
example, examine models with Cournot and Bertrand competition and find that with
plausible levels of sunk costs, anticompetitive mergers are unlikely to generate entry.
Notwithstanding this finding, courts have found that evidence of likelihood of entry
into a market substantially lessens the concern that a merger in that market would be
harmful (see, e.g., U.S. v. Syufy Enterprise, 1990; U.S. v. Baker Hughes, 1990).
Surprisingly, given the importance of entry in antitrust analysis, there is relatively
little detailed economic research examining intermediate-run market dynamics in the
narrow product categories that are typically the focus of antitrust analysis.2The purpose
of this paper is to develop this type of evidence by focusing intensively on a single
important industry, big-box grocery retailing in the U.S., over a five-year period. Retail
markets are often viewed as markets in which entry and expansion should be relatively
easy such that even the threat of entry is seen as sufficient to maintain competition
(U.S. v.Syufy Enterprise, 1990). Relative to many sectors, entry requirements in retailing
markets are not particularly onerous. With an existing supply network, a retailer need
only identify an effective location and obtain permission from local regulators to open an
establishment. Notwithstanding the perceived ease of entry and expansion, mergers in
retail markets are often subject to material antitrust review. Between 1998 and 2007, for
example, the FTC investigated supermarket mergers affecting 153 antitrust markets and
challenged mergers in 134 of those markets.3Evidence on observed market dynamics in a
retail market provides important information that can allow regulators to better evaluate
the credibility of claims that potential entry or expansion by incumbents can discipline
markets in response to mergers that substantially increase market concentration.
Our paper has six findings. First, we find that despite being a mature industry,the
big-box grocery retailing is remarkably dynamic. While the number of big-box grocery
outlets operating in the U.S. has remained roughly constant, each year roughly 7% of
retail outlets either open or close. Some of this turnover is the result of rapid growth
of supercenter and club retailers at the expense of traditional supermarkets. Still, even
traditional supermarket retailers continue to open new stores representing roughly 2%
of the stock of existing stores each year.
Second, we find that entry and exit are quite common for small independent
supermarkets (single outlet firms) and supermarkets owned by small chains (chains with
1. U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2010),
section 9.
2. Notable exceptions are studies of the cement industry (e.g., Syverson, 2008), the airline industry (e.g.,
Goolsbee and Syverson, 2008), and the banking industry (e.g., Berger et al., 2004).
3. See FTC (2008), Table 4-2.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT