Drilling and Debt

AuthorERIK P. GILJE,DANIEL MURPHY,ELENA LOUTSKINA
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12884
Published date01 June 2020
Date01 June 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 3 JUNE 2020
Drilling and Debt
ERIK P. GILJE, ELENA LOUTSKINA, and DANIEL MURPHY
ABSTRACT
This paper documents a previously unrecognized debt-related investment distortion.
Using detailed project-level data for 69 firms in the oil and gas industry, wefind that
highly levered firms pull forward investment, completing projects early at the expense
of long-run project returns and project value. This behavior is particularly pronounced
prior to debt renegotiations. We test several channels that could explain this behavior
and find evidence consistent with equity holders sacrificing long-run project returns
to enhance collateral values and, by extension, mitigate lending frictions at debt
renegotiations.
UNDERSTANDING HOW DEBT AFFECTS a firm’s investment decisions is one of
the central questions in finance. Incentive conflicts between debt and equity
claimants have the potential to result in inefficient and value-destroying de-
cisions (Jensen and Meckling (1976)). Existing theoretical and empirical work
has focused largely on the size, prevalence, and mitigation of investment distor-
tions linked with the traditional agency costs of debt such as underinvestment
and risk-shifting.1
In this paper, we use new detailed project-level data to document a previously
unrecognized debt-related investment distortion. We show that high-leverage
Erik P. Gilje is with the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER. Elena Lout-
skina and Daniel Murphy are with the University of Virginia Darden School of Business. Wewould
like to thank Steve Baker; David De Angelis; Michael Faulkender; Vincent Glode; Rustom Irani;
Don Keim; Doron Levit; Song Ma; Greg Nini; Krishna Ramaswamy; Julio Riutort; Michael Roberts;
Mike Schwert; Phil Strahan; Mathieu Taschereau-Dumouchel; Luke Taylor; Hongda Zhong; and
seminar participants at Wharton, Dartmouth (Tuck), University of Virginia (Darden), IU Bloom-
ington, GWU, the 2016 MIT Junior Faculty Conference, 9th Annual FSU SunTrust Beach Confer-
ence, 2017 PNC University of Kentucky Finance Conference, 14th Annual Conference in Financial
Economic Research IDC, 2017 Frontiers of Finance Conference, 2017 Financial Intermediation Re-
search Society Conference, and Finance—UC 12th International Conference for helpful comments.
We would also like to thank Julia Tulloh for her valuable research assistance, and the Rodney L.
White center for financial support. We have read The Journal of Finance disclosure policy and
have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: Erik P. Gilje, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust
Walk - SHDH 2456, Philadelphia, PA,19104; e-mail: gilje@wharton.upenn.edu.
1Theoretical work that focuses on these issues includes, for example, Aghion and Bolton (1992),
Bolton and Scharfstein (1990), Hart and Moore (1995, 1998), Jensen and Meckling (1976), and
Myers (1977). Empirical work includes Andrade and Kaplan (1998), Parrino and Weisbach (1999),
Eisdorfer (2008), Almeida, Campello, and Weisbach (2011), and Gilje (2016).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12884
C2020 the American Finance Association
1287
1288 The Journal of Finance R
firms facing debt renegotiations pull investment forward and complete projects
early at the expense of project net present value (NPV). These negative project-
level investment distortions likely aim to enhance collateral value, thereby
mitigating lending frictions and increasing firms’ access to finance. Overall,
our results suggest that by increasing collateral value, high-leverage firms
(dependent on asset-based loans) mitigate financing frictions that arise at debt
renegotiations. This finding also highlights a previously unexplored hidden
cost of collateral-based financing.
Identifying how debt affects firms’ actions is empirically challenging. First,
it is difficult to observe actions at the project level and identify how these
actions affect firms’ cash flows. Second, even if one can observe managers’
detailed actions, assessing whether a decision is value maximizing requires
that a clear, unambiguous counterfactual decision exists and that its value
be observable. Third, leverage and the composition of credit agreements are
not randomly assigned, and omitted endogenous variables could be related to
both firm-level investment decisions and leverage, making it difficult to infer a
causal relationship. Finally, the distortive effects of debt tend to arise only in
the presence of market frictions that intensify as leverage increases (see, e.g.,
Stein (2003)).2
We exploit an empirical setting that allows us to make significant progress
on the above challenges. Specifically, we use detailed project-level completion
decisions from North American shale oil drilling projects to examine how oil
and gas companies with different levels of leverage react to the severe contango
episode that began in December 2014. This setting has several advantages.
First, we observe high-frequency project-level company decisions and can
quantify the effects of completing an individual oil well versus delaying com-
pletion of the well. Our data set contains detailed project-level data on 3,557
North American shale oil wells operated by 69 publicly traded oil and gas
firms. We know the date of well spudding (project start) and well completion
(first production and project cash flow), as well as the precise location of the
well.
Second, the 2014 to 2015 contango episode offers a clear instance in which
completion should be delayed. During this period, oil spot prices were signifi-
cantly lower than oil futures prices. In February 2015, for example, six-month
oil futures prices were 11% higher than spot prices (Figure 1). The futures curve
provides us with a clear counterfactual as it allows us to estimate the value
of delaying completion. We show that a decision to accelerate well completion
and to start oil production early is not value maximizing at the project level.3
Third, the detailed project-level data allow us to make progress in control-
ling for the endogeneity of potential differences in investment opportunities
2In a frictionless world, investment is independent of firm leverage and depends only on invest-
ment opportunities (Modigliani and Miller (1958)).
3Production from shale oil projects is highest during the first month and declines in each
subsequent month. Consequently, pricing at the time of initial production is a key determinant of
project-level returns.
Drilling and Debt 1289
Panel
0
1
1
1
futures price rel ative t o current s pot pric e
Pane
B. February
0
.95
1
.05
1.1
.15
1.2
.25
1.3
el A. Crude
y 2015 and
5
Matur
i
Futures curve
s
Futures curve
Futures curve
Oil Futures
September
10
i
ty of futures cont
r
s
before contang
o
as of September
as of February 2
0
s Prices over
2014 Oil Pr
15
r
act (Months )
o
and during cont
a
2014
0
15
r Time
rice Futures
20
a
ngo
s Curves
Figure 1. Crude oil futures price dynamics. Panel A plots the difference between the six-
month (two-year) futures and the spot price normalized by the spot price between 2012 and 2016,
crude oil futures prices came from Bloomberg. The shaded area represents the contango period
that we focus on in our study.Panel B plots the crude oil futures curve normalized by the spot price
at two different points in time: September 2014, prior to the contango, and February 2015, during
the contango episode. (Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT