Diversity, Social Goods Provision, and Performance in the Firm

AuthorWallace P. Mullin,Sara Fisher Ellison
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12051
Date01 June 2014
Published date01 June 2014
Diversity, Social Goods Provision, and Performance
in the Firm
SARA FISHER ELLISON
Department of Economics
MIT, Cambridge, MA 02142
sellison@mit.edu
WALLACE P. MULLIN
Department of Economics
George Washington University
Washington, DC 20052
wpmullin@gwu.edu
Economists have studied the effect of diversity on the provision of social goods and the stock
of social capital. In parallel, management scholars have studied the effect of diversity in the
workplace on firm performance. We integrate these two growing literatures and explore these
questions with a unique dataset. A firm provided eight years of individual-level employee survey
data, which include measures of the stock of social capital, plus office-level measures of diversity
and performance. We find some evidence that more gender-homogeneous offices enjoy higher
levels of social goods provision but those offices do not perform any better and may actually
perform worse.
1. Introduction
Legal and societal shifts in 20th Century America laid the groundwork for increased
diversity in many settings. Schools ceased to be racially segregated. Barriers to female
and minority employment diminished, leading to more diverse workplaces. Greater
mobility resulted in neighborhoods fragmented in various dimensions. The consequent
social benefits of this increased diversity, though difficult to quantify, may be quite
important. With these broad social changes as a backdrop, the focus of this paper is
smaller but sharper.We are interested in how diversity in a group affects the provision of
social goods in the group, and then, ultimately,performance of that group. In particular,
we focus attention on diversity in a market environment, that created by a firm and its
workforce. Regardless of the cause of the increased workplace diversity, it is the job of the
managers to encourage the greatest productivity possible from their units, maximizing
profits, perhaps, or some other quantifiable outcome. It is our goal, then, to shed light
on how diversity is associated with those outcomes.
Because these and related questions of diversity, social goods, and performance
are of fundamental interest outside of workplace settings as well, it is not surprising
that our research bears upon several strands of literature, including ones in strategic
Ellison thanks the NSF for its support and the Institute for Advanced Study for its support and hospitality
while conducting this research as the Richard B. Fisher Member. Mullin thanks the GWIPP for its research
support. Jeffrey Greenbaumprovided excellent research assistance. Glenn Ellison, a coeditor and referees, and
various seminar participants have provided very useful comments and suggestions. Finally, we especially
thank to John Chuang and Matthew Grant for their invaluable assistance in providing these data.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 2, Summer 2014, 465–481
466 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
management, organizational behavior, sociology, and economics. Economists and soci-
ologists have focused more on the first of our two questions, how diversity in a group
affects the provision of social goods. Management scholars, in contrast, have focused
more on the second question, how diversity affects the performance of the group. In fact,
part of the contribution we see this paper making is to serve as a sort of bridge between
those literatures.
Economists’ interest in the effect of diversity on the provision of social goods is
ongoing. Studies have found evidence that social goods are provided at a lower level in
communities exhibiting fragmentation on various dimensions. Vigdor (2004) finds that
census response rates are lower in census tracts with higher ethnic fragmentation. Costa
and Kahn (2003) find that desertion rates are higher in Civil Warmilitary companies with
higher age and occupational fragmentation. Glaeser et al. (2000) find that trust is lower
among Harvard undergraduates when race and nationality fragmentation is higher.
Several studies have documented that school funding is higher in more homogenous
communities (see, e.g., Goldin and Katz, 1999; Poterba, 1997; Miguel and Gugerty,2005).1
These results may be quite important in contexts where social goods provision is the
output of interest. However, in some contexts, the social good may be an “intermediate
good.” In the workplace, cooperation, trust, and other social goods may be important
elements of the functioning of an office, but firm owners ultimately care about an office’s
performance, as reflected in revenues, costs, and profits. We would also like to address
this additional question, so often missing in the economics literature.
Not surprisingly, a sizeable management literature on diversity and performance
exists.2This literature has seen a recent emphasis on the importance of “context” on
the effect that diversity has on performance (see Joshi and Roh, 2009). In other words,
covariates such as industry, profession, and organizational culture could play a role in
determining diversity’s effect. In fact, if we think of the level of social goods in a group
as an element of context, our two-step analysis elucidates the role of context variables
and the mechanisms by which they are important.
Finally, we draw on a paper by Rob and Zemsky (2002), which provides a formal
model of social capital. Modifying their model, we elucidate how diversity could in-
fluence the accumulation of social capital and allow a separate channel for diversity to
affect office performance directly. This model provides testable hypotheses, which can
be evaluated in our empirical setting or by other researchers in different settings.
We have a unique data set from a firm that operates numerous small offices in the
United States and abroad. They have provided us with eight years of individual-level
employee survey data as well as office-level measures of diversity and performance.
The survey data furnish us with several indicators of firm social capital, such the level
of cooperation among employees. The data allow us to address two distinct questions.
First, broadly speaking, do we find lower levels of social goods provision in more
diverse offices? Such a finding has been made in the economics literature cited above,
but our results provide an interesting complement to those: economists have previously
focused on the effects of diversity in communities instead of workplaces,3and we
measure diversity on two dimensions not explored in this literature, gender and tenure.
We do find that higher office-level gender diversity is associated with lower employee
cooperation, but that tenure diversity has little or no effect.
1. See also Costa and Kahn (2003) for an excellent survey of this literature.
2. Two comprehensivesurveys are Williams and O’Reilly (1998) and Shore et al. (2009).
3. Costa and Kahn’s study of Union Army troops is a possible exception.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT