Diversification, Organization, and Value of the Firm

Date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12108
AuthorTatsuo Ushijima
Published date01 May 2016
Diversification, Organization, and Value
of the Firm
Tatsuo Ushijima
Because corporate diversification coevolves with organizational structure,a discount for diversi-
fication, which is widely documented in the literature, can be caused by organizational structure
rather than by the industrial scope of the firm. I examine this possibility based on a large sample
of Japanese firms for which the legal (parent–subsidiary) structure of the organization is easily
observable. I identify a significant discount for diversified firms with and without control over the
organizational structure. I also find that firms with a legally segmented structure (e.g., holding
companies) are deeply discounted. My results suggest that diversification and organization are
both important determinants of firm value.
The effect of industrial diversification on firm value has been an intensely debated issue
in finance since the 1990s. Berger and Ofek (1995) and Lang and Stulz (1994) find that
diversified firms trade at a substantial discount relative to a portfolio of representative focused
(single-business) firms in the same industries. These and other early studies attribute the
discount to inefficiencies caused by diversification. In particular, Shin and Stulz (1998) and
Rajan, Servaes, and Zingales (2000) suggest that diversification results in inefficient internal
capital markets that allocate funds less (more) than optimally to (un)promising opportunities.
However, more recent studies suspect that diversification discounts are caused by factors other
than diversification itself. Understanding the true effect of diversification by identifying such
confounding factors is a common theme among recent theoretical and empirical works, in
particular those of Klein and Saidenberg (2010) and Sanzhar (2006), which have added an
interesting new perspective to the ongoing debate.1
Klein and Saidenberg (2010) find that the market value of bank holding companies decreases
with the number of subsidiary banks, a measure of organizational complexity for these
corporations. Sanzhar (2006) finds that pseudo-conglomerates (multiple-segment f irms that
operate in only one industry) and real conglomerates are similarly discounted by the market. He
argues that pseudo-conglomerates are discounted because their organization is more complex
than the organization of single-segment, focused firms. Based on these observations, Klein and
Saidenberg (2010) and Sanzhar (2006) hypothesize that the discount for diversified firms arises,
I am grateful for the helpful comments receivedfrom an anonymous referee, Raghavendra Rau (Editor), Yoshiro Tsutsui,
Hirofumi Uchida, Hideaki Miyajima, Masayuki Morikawa,Ryo Ogawa, Hideo Owan, Christina Ahmadjian, and seminar
participants at Kobe University, AoyamaGakuin University, the Research Institute of Economy, Tradeand Industry, the
Asian Finance Association, the World Banking and Finance Symposium, and the Western Economic Association. Any
remaining errors are mine.This study was funded by KAKENHI (Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research), Grant Number
24530421.
Tatsuo Ushijima is fromthe Faculty of Business and Commerce, Keio University in Tokyo, Japan.
1Matsusaka (2001), Bernardo and Chowdhry (2002), and Gomes and Livdan (2004) develop models in which diver-
sification discounts endogenously arise from the value-maximizing behavior of firms. Campa and Kedia (2002) and
Villalonga (2004) show, based on data up to the mid-1990s, that diversification discounts disappear when accounting for
the endogeneity of diversification However, based on more recent data, Hoechle et al. (2012) identify a diversification
discount that is robust to various controls for endogeneity.
Financial Management Summer 2016 pages 467 – 499
468 Financial Management rSummer 2016
at least in part, from a complex, difficult-to-manage structure of these fir ms rather than solely
from their industrial scope.
Diversified firms typically have a more complex organizational structure than focused firms
because, as suggested by Chandler’s (1962) dictum that “structure follows strategy,” a diversifica-
tion strategy entails not only the enlargement of industrial scope but also the alignment of internal
structure to the increased scope. If the discount for diversified fir ms emanates from failures of this
strategy,part of the discount can be attributed to organizational structure and par t can be attributed
to scope. Moreover,the financial implications of the firm’sinternal str ucture are barelyunderstood
by academic researchers. Thus, the hypothesisof Klein and Saidenberg (2010) and Sanzhar (2006)
suggests an interesting new avenuefor research. Is organization a fundamental determinant of f irm
value, which is potentially as important as industry scope? If so, how does it affectf irm value? In
this article, I seek to answer these questions by jointlyestimating the effects of diversification and
organization on firm value within the standard framework of diversification discount research.
A simultaneous estimation of the values of diversification and organization is subject to two
difficulties. The first is how to observe organizational structure for a large sample of firms. Unlike
diversification, which is observable through segmental reporting, a firm’sorganization is diff icult
to observe based on public data. To collect information on corporate structure, researchers
often rely on proprietary surveys, which naturally limit the size and scope of a research sample.
Second, firm organization is difficult to grasp comprehensively because it is multifaceted by
nature, and many of its aspects defy quantification. Finding an economically important aspect
of organization that is also measurable at low cost is therefore crucial for empirical studies.
I approach this task by focusing on the legal (parent-subsidiary) structure of Japanese firms.
For firms forming a new business unit, a fundamental choice is whether to organize the unit
as a subsidiary, which is a legal entity distinct from the parent (headquarters), or as an internal
division of the parent.2The organization of firms that choose the former option becomes more
segmented than it would otherwise be due to internal legal boundaries. Empirical research on the
legal structure of the firm is scant at best. However, as I showin the next section, the structure can
affect firm value through various channels, such as the decision-making incentives of managers,
internal differentiation of financial and nonfinancial contracts, and interdivisional fund flows.
I focus on legal structure, as it nontrivially differentiates the organizations of Japanese firms.
In particular, diversified firms tend to have a legally more segmented structure than focused
firms because subsidiaries are often used as an organizational vehicle for diversification. The
legal structure of Japanese firms is also easy to observe because Japan’s financial reporting
system requires firms to f ile unconsolidated (parent-only) as well as consolidated (parent plus
subsidiaries) financial statements. By comparing the two types of statements, one can easily
grasp the weight of subsidiaries (e.g., share of subsidiary employees in total employment) in a
firm’s organization. Moreover, the legal structure of Japanese firms has evolved considerably
in this century. A particularly noteworthy phenomenon is the diffusion of the holding-company
structure, which had been prohibited by law until 1997. These dynamics enable the use of
longitudinal variations to identify the value of organization.
My analyses are based on a large panel of public firms from 2001 to 2010. Using the excess
value measure developed by Berger and Ofek (1995), I estimate the values of diversification and
organizational structure with two distinct methods: regression and propensity-score matching
estimation. My regressions consistently reveal a significant discount for diversified firms; ceteris
paribus, diversified firms trade at a discount of 5% to 9% relative to focused f irms in the same
2If the business unit is acquired from outside the firm, the decision becomes a choice between takeover, whichmakes the
target a subsidiary of the acquiring firm, and merger, which assimilates the target into the acquiring firm’s organization.
Ushijima rDiversification and Organizational Discounts 469
industries. Although this effect is smaller in magnitude than discounts typically reported for
US firms, it is robust to f irm fixed effects, which show that excess value contains substantial
permanent components. Consistent with the organizational hypothesis, the diversification
discount decreases in size when organizational structure is taken into account but does not
disappear. Another important finding is that firms with a legally segmented structure are
discounted by the market. In particular, firms with a holding-company structure are, on average,
valued 8% to 10% lower than firms with a more centralized structure. Therefore, my regressions
reveal an organizational discount that is no smaller than the discount for industry diversification.
These findings survive various robustness checks, including alternative measures of firm value,
additional control variables, and quantile regressions.
The propensity-score matching estimation compares the changes in excess value after a large
discrete shift in diversification status or organizational structure (treatment) between treated
firms (i.e., diversifying/refocusing firms and f irms adopting a holding-company structure) and
untreated (comparison) firms that do not exhibit the shift. Probit regressions show that for each
treatment, treated and untreated firms systematically differ from each other. Therefore, I perform
propensity-score matching to create a sample of control firms that are comparable to treated
firms in terms of the ex ante probability of receiving a treatment. I compare changes (differences)
rather than levels of excess value because difference-in-differencesmatching estimation is robust
to endogeneity due to unobserved persistent factors as well as observed time-varying factors.
Consistent with the regression results summarized above, the matching estimates of the values of
diversification and holding-company structure are negative and significant. Specifically, the value
of diversifying firms declines, on average, 6% to 13% vis-`
a-vis control firms in one to three years
following diversification. In contrast, the value of refocusing firms increases 8% to 12% after
refocusing relative to comparable diversified firms that choose not to refocus. The value of firms
adopting a holding-company structure declines 8% to 13% compared to non-adopting firms.
Overall, my findings can be summarized as follows. First, diversified Japanese firms trade at
a discount that is robust to controls for endogeneity. Second, organizational structure is no less
important than industrial scope as a determinant of fir m value.In par ticular,I f ind a large discount
for firms with a legally segmented structure, such as holding companies. Because legal structure
is but one aspect of corporate organization, the overall effect of organization can be greater than
that suggested by the results cited herein. At the same time, however, it should be noted that
organizational variables do not explain away the diversification discount even when unobserved
aspects of corporate organization are controlled by firm fixed effects. The results therefore
suggest that diversification and organization are both important determinants of firm value.
This article contributes to the diversification discount literature by providing evidence that is
robust to controls for endogeneity as well as by conducting the first formal test of the organi-
zational hypothesis.3By estimating the value of legal structure, it also adds to the burgeoning
empirical literature on decentralization (delegation of decision rights to operating managers).
Organizational economists have theorized that decentralization increases firm performance by
enabling firms to better adapt to operating environments (e.g., Aghion and Tirole, 1997). The
discount for legally segmented structure identified in this article is not consistent with this
view because subsidiary managers are normally delegated more decision rights than comparable
managers within the parent firms. A better understanding of the cost of decentralized decision
making is likely necessary. The discount also bears on research regarding stock pyramids. The
3Klein and Saidenberg (2010) estimate the value of organizational form, but their analysis is based on bank holding
companies, which are essentially focused firms. Sanzhar (2006) compares diversified and focused firms but does not
directly observe organization.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT