Diagnostic Expectations and Stock Returns

AuthorANDREI SHLEIFER,NICOLA GENNAIOLI,RAFAEL LA PORTA,PEDRO BORDALO
Published date01 December 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12833
Date01 December 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2019
Diagnostic Expectations and Stock Returns
PEDRO BORDALO, NICOLA GENNAIOLI, RAFAEL LA PORTA,
and ANDREI SHLEIFER
ABSTRACT
We revisit La Porta’s finding that returns on stocks with the most optimistic ana-
lyst long-term earnings growth forecasts are lower than those on stocks with the
most pessimistic forecasts. We document the joint dynamics of fundamentals, expec-
tations, and returns of these portfolios, and explain the facts using a model of belief
formation based on the representativeness heuristic. Analysts forecast fundamentals
from observed earnings growth, but overreact to news by exaggerating the probability
of states that have become more likely.We find support for the model’s predictions. A
quantitative estimation of the model accounts for the key patterns in the data.
LAPORTA (1996)SHOWS THAT STOCK market analysts’ expectations of the long-
term earnings growth of the companies they cover have strong predictive power
for these companies’ future stock returns. Companies whose earnings growth
analysts are most optimistic about earn poor returns relative to companies
whose analysts are most pessimistic about. Betting against extreme analyst
optimism has thus been a good idea on average. La Porta (1996) interprets
this finding as evidence that analysts, as well as investors who follow them or
think like them, are too optimistic about stocks with rapidly growing earnings
and too pessimistic about stocks with deteriorating earnings. As a result, the
former stocks are overvalued, the latter are undervalued, and the predictability
of returns is driven by the correction of expectations.
In this paper, we revisit this puzzle using a model of Kahneman and Tver-
sky’s (1972) representativeness heuristic developed by Gennaioli and Shleifer
(2010) and Bordalo et al. (2016). Relative to the existing work, we make three
innovations. First, we rely on a portable and psychologically founded model
that has been used to describe the dynamics of beliefs in a variety of settings,
not only in the one at hand. Second, we assess the qualitative and quantita-
tive performance of this model in explaining not only a cross-section of stock
Pedro Bordalo is with Sa¨
ıd Business School, University of Oxford. Nicola Gennaioli is with
Bocconi University and IGIER. Rafael La Porta is with Brown University. Andrei Shleifer is with
Harvard University. Nicola Gennaioli thanks the European Research Council (GA 647782) and
Andrei Shleifer thanks the Pershing Square Venture Fund for Research on the Foundations of
Human Behavior for financial support of this research. We are grateful to seminar participants at
Brown University and Sloan School, and especially to Josh Schwartzstein, Jesse Shapiro, Pietro
Veronesi, Yang You,and the referees for helpful comments. We also thank V. V. Chari, who encour-
aged us to confront our model of diagnostic expectations with the Kalman filter. The authors have
no relevant or material financial interests that relate to the research described in this paper.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12833
2839
2840 The Journal of Finance R
returns, but also the paths of fundamentals leading to overvaluation and of an-
alyst expectations. Third, we test new predictions that distinguish our model
from mechanical models of extrapolation such as adaptive expectations. These
new predictions follow from the fact that in our model expectations contain a
“kernel of truth” in that they exaggerate true features of reality. Beliefs thus
move in the correct direction, but by more than the right amount.
As a first step, we look at the data (described in Section I). In Section II,we
confirm with 20 additional years of data La Porta’s (1996) finding that stocks
with low long-term earnings growth forecasts (LLTG stocks) outperform stocks
with high long-term earnings growth forecasts (HLTG stocks). Wethen present
three additional facts. First, HLTG stocks exhibit fast past earnings growth,
which slows down going forward. Second, forecasts of future earnings growth
of HLTG stocks are too optimistic, and are systematically revised downward
later. Third, HLTG stocks exhibit good past returns but their returns going
forward are low. The opposite dynamics obtain for LLTG stocks, but in a less
extreme form. We do not account for this asymmetry in our model.
The data suggest that analysts use a firm’s past performance to infer its
future performance, but overreact. This updating mechanism arises naturally
from overweighting of representative types. Gennaioli and Shleifer (2010)and
Bordalo et al. (2016) model a type tas representative of a group Gwhen it occurs
more frequently in that group than in a reference group G. For instance,
after a positive medical test, the representative patient is t=“sick” because
sick people are truly more prevalent among those who tested positive than in
the overall population. After such a positive test, the representative sick type
quickly comes to mind and the doctor inflates its probability too much, which
may still be objectively low if the disease is rare (Casscells, Schoenberger, and
Graboys (1978)). There is a kernel of truth in departures from rationality: the
doctor overreacts to the objectively useful information from the test.
In Section III, we incorporate this model of representativeness into a problem
of an analyst learning about a firm’s unobserved fundamentals in light of a
noisy signal such as current earnings. This approach yields a distorted Kalman
filter, which we refer to as the “diagnostic Kalman filter,” that overinflates
the probability of future earnings growth realizations whose likelihood has
objectively increased the most in light of recent news. After strong earnings
growth, the probability that the firm is the next “Google” goes up. This type
becomes representative and analysts inflate its probability excessively, even
though Googles remain rare in absolute terms. As good news stops arriving,
overoptimism cools off. Rapid earnings growth thus causes overvaluation and
subsequent disappointment, leading to reversals of optimism and low returns.
In Section IV, we show that this model makes predictions consistent with the
evidence in Section II. In Section V, we perform a first pass quantitative assess-
ment of the model. We first show that expectations data point to overreaction
to news, in the sense that revisions of the forecast of LTG negatively predict
errors in that forecast. We then use the simulated method of moments (SMM)
to estimate the parameter controlling the strength of representativeness by
matching observed overreaction and the empirical moments of the earnings
Diagnostic Expectations and Stock Returns 2841
process. We find that forecasters react about twice as much to information as is
objectively warranted. This estimate lies in the ballpark of those obtained us-
ing the expectations of professional forecasters about credit spreads (Bordalo,
Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2018)) and many macroeconomic variables (Bordalo
et al. (2018)). We also find that stocks overreact to news over a time scale of
about three years. Notably, while the estimation uses expectations and fun-
damentals alone, it predicts the observed return spread between LLTG and
HLTG stocks reasonably well.
In Section VI, we test three novel predictions of the model, all following from
the kernel-of-truth property as applied to the present dynamic setting. First,
we show that the HLTG group contains a fat right tail of future exceptional
performers, and that analysts attach an excessively high probability that HLTG
firms are in that tail. There are very few Googles, but they are concentrated
in the HLTG group, and analysts exaggerate their frequency. This is precisely
what the kernel-of-truth property of expectations predicts.
Second, we show that the return spread between LLTG and HLTG stocks
widens among firms with more volatile or persistent fundamentals. This is
also in line with the kernel of truth: in both cases, good news is even more
informative about strong future performance, which renders Googles even more
representative. Third, we show that expectations about HLTG (LLTG) stocks
revert downward (upward) even in the absence of bad (good) news. This is
again in line with the kernel of truth: analyst forecasts reflect the true mean
reversion in earnings growth.
Mechanical models of beliefs, such as adaptive expectations, cannot yield
these facts, which are due to the forward-looking but not fully rational learning
that we see in the data.
Our paper follows extensive research on overreaction and volatility that be-
gins with Shiller (1981), De Bondt and Thaler (1985,1987), Cutler, Poterba, and
Summers (1990,1991), and De Long et al. (1990a,1990b). This work often uses
mechanical rules for belief updating such as adaptive expectations or adaptive
learning (e.g., Barsky and De Long (1993), Barberis et al. (2015), Adam, Marcet,
and Beutel (2017)).1Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) is closest in spirit,
though not in formulation, to our current work, since it is also motivated by rep-
resentativeness. The authors present a model of Bayesian learning in which the
decision maker is trying to distinguish models that are all incorrect. Because
they do not model representativeness explicitly, their specification does not al-
low for a tight link between measurable reality and measurable beliefs that is
central to our theory and evidence. Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subramanyam
(1998) and Odean (1998) model investor overconfidence, the tendency of
1Other papers include Barberis and Shleifer (2003), Glaeser and Nathanson (2015), Hong and
Stein (1999), Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1994), Marcet and Sargent (1989), and Adam,
Marcet, and Nicolini (2016). In Adam, Marcet, and Beutel (2017), agents learn the mapping between
fundamentals and prices, but they are rational about fundamentals. Pastor and Veronesi (2003,
2005,2009) present rational learning models in which uncertainty about the fundamentals of
some firms can yield predictability in aggregate stock returns. This approach does not analyze
expectations data or cross-sectional differences in returns.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT