Demonstrating Absence of Anticompetitive Effects

Pages187-228
CHAPTER VI
DEMONSTRATING ABSENCE OF
ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS
If, after the relevant market has been properly defined and market
shares calculated, the proposed merger would create a high level of
concentration, the market structure will raise an inference that either
unilateral or coordinated anticompetitive effects may result. Left
unrebutted, such an inference could provide sufficient grounds to
prohibit the transaction under Section 7 of the Clayton Act (Section 7).1
Market definition and market shares are not necessarily dispositive,
however. The merging parties can rebut the inference that even a highly-
concentrated market is likely to lead to anticompetitive results.
A. The Significance of Market Shares, Market Structure, and
Concentration
Since 1974, defendants have relied on the Supreme Court’s decision
in United States v. General Dynamics Corp.2 to rebut inferences that
arise from high market shares. In General Dynamics, the Antitrust
Division of the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ or the Division)
challenged the combination of two major coal producers that resulted in
“undue concentration” of past coal production in the relevant geographic
market3 sufficient to support “prima facie violations of Section 7 of the
Clayton Act.”4 Nevertheless, the Court concluded that the merger was
not illegal in light of “other pertinent factors” affecting the market.5
The Court observed that although “[e]vidence of the amount of
annual sales is relevant as a prediction of future competitive strength,” it
does not, “as a matter of logic, necessarily give a proper picture of a
company’s future ability to compete.”6 In addition to evaluating market
1. 15 U.S.C. § 18.
2. 415 U.S. 486 (1974).
3. Id. at 497-98.
4. Id. at 496 (citing Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962)
and United States v. Philadelphia Nat’l Bank, 374 U.S. 321 (1966)).
5. General Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 498.
6. Id. at 501.
187
188 Mergers and Acquisitions
shares and concentration, a court should analyze the “structure, history
and probable future” of the relevant product market. Because electric
utilities bought coal under long-term contracts, the better measure of a
coal company’s ability to compete for future contracts was the size of its
uncommitted reserves, not its past production.7 Based on this measure,
the Court concluded that the parties’ current market position and overall
concentration did not show the true competitive effects likely to result
from the transaction.8
Following General Dynamics, courts have held that merging parties
may rebut a presumption of anticompetitive effects based on market
shares and concentration by showing those statistics do not accurately
predict the transaction’s future competitive effects.9 In United States v.
Baker Hughes,10 the D.C. Circuit incorporated General Dynamics into its
burden-shifting approach to merger analysis.11 There, the DOJ
challenged the combination of two sellers of hardrock hydraulic
underground drilling rigs (HHUDRs) that resulted in a combined market
share of 76 percent and in an increase in Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
(HHI) levels from 2878 to 4303,12 which was sufficient to support “a
prima facie case of anticompetitive effect.”13 Nevertheless, the court held
that the merger was not unlawful in light of “the flawed underpinnings of
the government’s prima facie case,” the “sophistication of HHUDR
consumers,” and ease of entry.14
The court first rejected the Division’s argument that a prima facie
case could be rebutted only by evidence of ease of entry. It observed that
“[i]n the wake of General Dynamics, the Supreme Court and lower
courts . . . have successfully rebutted the government’s prima facie case
7. Id. at 501-02.
8. In so holding, the Co urt cited its anal ysis in Brown Shoe Co . v. United
States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962), which “cautioned that statistics concerning
market share and concentration, while of great significance, were not
conclusive indicators of anticompetitive effects.” General Dynamics,
415 U.S. at 498.
9. See, e.g., United States v. Citizens and S. Nat’l Bank, 42 2 U.S. 86, 121
(1975).
10. 908 F.2d 981 (D.C. Cir. 1990).
11. Id. at 982-83 (citing General Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 496-504).
12. Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d at 983 n.3.
13. Id. at 983.
14. Id. at 986.
Demonstrating Absence of Anticompetitive Effects 189
by presenting evidence on a variety of factors other than ease of entry.”15
Next, the court explained that in a small market with infrequent sales a
snapshot of market share at any particular point in time likely does not
accurately reflect the competitive strength of any given firm.16 The court
observed that the sophistication of HHUDR buyers “was likely to
promote competition even in a highly-concentrated market.”17 Finally,
the court determined that merging parties need not make a “clear
showing” to rebut the structural presumption. To require such a showing
would improperly “move far toward forcing a defendant to rebut a
probability with a certainty.”18 “In the aftermath of General Dynamics, a
defendant seeking to rebut a presumption of anticompetitive effect must
show that the prima facie case inaccurately predicts the relevant
transaction’s probable effect on future competition.”19 “The more
compelling the prima facie case, the more evidence the defendant must
present to rebut it successfully.”20
Since Baker Hughes, other circuit courts have adopted the same or
similar frameworks for analyzing mergers.21 Courts and the antitrust
agencies have continued to apply a rebuttable presumption of illegality22
15. Id. at 985.
16. Id. at 986.
17. Id. “These products are hardly trinkets sold to small consumers who may
possess imperfect information and limited bargaining power. HHUDR
buyers closely examine available options and typically insist on receiving
multiple, confidential bids for each order.” Id.
18. Id. at 989-92.
19. Id. at 991.
20. Id.
21. See, e.g., Chicago Bridge & Iron Co. N.V. v. FTC, 534 F.3d 410, 423 (5th
Cir. 2008) (adopting Baker Hughes’s burden shifting framework); FT C v.
Butterworth Health Corp., 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (same); FTC v.
University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1218-19 (11th Cir. 1991) (same).
22. The ultimate burden of proof in the case remains on the plaintiff. See,
e.g., Chicago Bridge & Iron Co., 534 F.3d at 423 (“[T]he ultimate burden
of persuasion . . . is incumbent on the Government at all times.”); Baker
Hughes, 908 F.2d at 991 (“If the burden of production imposed on a
defendant is unduly onerous, the distinction between that burden and the
ultimate burden of p ersuasionalways an e lusive distinctio n in
practicedisintegrates completely.”); United States v. H&R Block, Inc.,
833 F. Supp. 2d 36, 50 (D.D.C. 2011) (holding that “the ultimate burden
of persuasion . . . remains with the government at all times.”).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT