Debt Contracting on Management

Date01 August 2020
AuthorDAVID DE ANGELIS,BRIAN AKINS,MACLEAN GAULIN
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12893
Published date01 August 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2020
Debt Contracting on Management
BRIAN AKINS, DAVID DE ANGELIS, and MACLEAN GAULIN
ABSTRACT
Change of management restrictions (CMRs) in loan contracts give lenders explicit
ex ante control rights over managerial retention and selection. This paper shows
that lenders use CMRs to mitigate risks arising from CEO turnover, especially those
related to the loss of human capital and replacement uncertainty, thereby provid-
ing evidence that human capital risk affects debt contracting. With a CMR in place,
the likelihood of CEO turnover decreases by more than half, and future firm perfor-
mance improves when retention frictions are important, suggesting that lenders can
influence managerial turnover, even outside of default states, and help the borrower
retain talent.
The occurrence of any one or more of the following events shall constitute
an “Event of Default” by Borrower hereunder: [ ...]
(n) Change of Management.
If James Bazet shall cease to be the Chief Executive Officer of Borrower at
any time.
Debt contract with Cobra Electronics Corporation (2002)
Brian Akins is at Rice University. David De Angelis is at Rice University. Maclean Gaulin is
at the University of Utah. We thank Amit Seru (the Editor); an anonymous associate editor; two
anonymous referees; Kerry Back; Anne Beatty; Jonathan Bitting; Alex Butler; Alan Crane; Kevin
Crotty; Peter Demerjian; Dave Denis (discussant); Dick Dietrich; Jefferson Duarte; Aytekin Ertan;
Janet Gao; Yaniv Grinstein; Gustavo Grullon; Matthew Gustafson (discussant); Yael Hochberg;
Victoria Ivashina; S´
ebastien Michenaud; Yihui Pan (discussant); Andrea Pawliczek (discussant);
Mitchell Petersen; Paul Povel; K. Ramesh; Michael Roberts; Daniel Saavedra; Doug Skinner;
Ioannis Spyridopoulos; Joe Weber; James Weston; Regina Wittenberg-Moerman; Tzachi Zack;
Feng Zhang (discussant); and seminar participants at London Business School, The Ohio State
University, Rice University, University of Houston, the 2016 Academic Conference on Corporate
Governance at Drexel University, the 2016 Annual Meeting of the Financial Management Associ-
ation, the 2016 Annual Meeting of the Northern Finance Association, the 2016 Colorado Summer
Accounting Research Conference, the 2016 Lone Star Accounting Conference, and the 2017 SFS
Cavalcade North America Conference for helpful comments. We also thank Ryan Israelsen, Amir
Sufi, and Ekaterina Volkova for sharing their data. We are grateful for the excellent research
assistance provided by Wendy Chong, Asiya Kazi, Richie Ledo, Sophia Shao, and Richard Swartz.
All remaining errors are our own. We have read The Journal of Finance disclosure policy and have
no conflicts of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: David De Angelis, Jones Graduate School of Business, Rice University, 6100
Main Street, MS 531 Houston, TX 77005; e-mail: deangelis@rice.edu
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12893
C2020 the American Finance Association
2095
2096 The Journal of Finance R
LENDERS CAN INCLUDE CHANGE OF management restrictions (CMRs) in loan
contracts. These restrictions give lenders explicit ex ante control rights over
retention and/or selection decisions. The presence of these covenants directly
speaks first to the possibility of lenders addressing the human capital risk
associated with a manager and second to lenders having an active role in
corporate governance. In their seminal paper, Hart and Moore (1994) develop
a theory of debt based on firms’ inability to transfer human capital from the
individual to the firm, but little is known about how debtholders address this
risk. There is also little empirical evidence of debtholders’ influence on an
important aspect of a borrower’s governance, namely, managerial turnover,
outside of default events (Shleifer and Vishny (1997), Roberts and Sufi (2009)).1
In this paper, we fill these two gaps in the literature by documenting the
presence of CMRs in loan contracts and addressing the following questions: (i)
Why do lenders use CMRs? and (ii) What are the implications of CMR inclusion
for CEO turnover and future firm performance? Our sample consists of 15,501
private loan contracts for 4,411 borrowing firms for which we identify whether
a loan includes a CMR and, if so, the way it is implemented. We find that
CMRs generally concern firms’ CEOs, and that 8.5% (17.2%) of (small) firms
in our sample have a CMR in at least one loan. Although CMRs are relatively
uncommon, they appear to be important in certain loans, such as those for
small and risky firms.
Given the extensive evidence on other loan covenants, what unique role does
a CMR play? Like other covenants, CMRs provide a mechanism for creditors
to influence the borrower’s governance. Unlike other covenants, CMRs do not
restrict managerial actions or require that financial thresholds be met; rather,
they restrict managerial selection. By restricting a decision that is traditionally
seen as the responsibility of the board of directors, CMRs intrude into corporate
affairs, which can be risky for lenders. In particular, by contracting directly on
management, lenders can be considered insiders under the bankruptcy code,
and thus can be exposed to litigation from other stakeholders (Leichtling and
Wong ( 1997)). This risk of litigation could explain the relatively low use of
CMRs. Moreover, while violations of financial covenants tend to lead to CEO
removal (Nini, Smith, and Sufi (2012)), CMRs are specific to retaining a partic-
ular CEO.
Why do lenders use CMRs? The first hypothesis is that lenders include CMRs
to mitigate risks arising from CEO turnover (henceforth, the risk hypothesis).
A change in CEO is, in general, risky due to uncertainty about the poten-
tial change in operations (Berkovitch and Israel (1996), Grinstein (2006)). As
creditors are likely to favor less risky corporate policies (Jensen and Meckling
(1976)), they can use a CMR to reduce the likelihood of CEO turnover. CEO
1Previous results suggest that lenders can force executive replacement in the case of bankruptcy
(Gilson (1989)) or covenant violations (Nini, Smith, and Sufi (2012)). However, this evidence re-
lates only to ex post renegotiation events that arise when the firm has been performing poorly
and is in payment or technical default. Little is known about creditor influence on turnover out-
side of these default events, or whether lenders are directly involved in managerial retention or
selection decisions.
Debt Contracting on Management 2097
turnovers are also risky because the human capital associated with the cur-
rent CEO is lost, and the board’s ability to find an appropriate replacement is
uncertain (Becker (1964)). Certainly, human capital risk also matters to share-
holders, who should try to retain valuable CEOs. However, it may be difficult
for shareholders to ensure CEO retention, especially when they face contract-
ing frictions. In such cases, a CMR helps protect banks by giving them control
rights during a turnover. Additionally, a CMR could increase the likelihood of
CEO retention because lenders can threaten to recall the loan due to a CMR
violation if the CEO quits. Recalling a loan will negatively impact the firm’s
share price, making it costly for a CEO holding shares of the firm to leave. The
second hypothesis concerns the possibility of lenders and the CEO colluding
to protect the CEO’s tenure via the use of a CMR (henceforth, the collusion
hypothesis). Under this hypothesis, lenders include a CMR in exchange for
securing the lending relationship or for a higher interest rate.
We start by investigating the risk hypothesis. Our initial evidence that CMRs
are used more frequently for small and risky borrowers supports the view that
a CMR can help lenders manage the operating risk related to CEO turnover.
For these firms, a negative shock associated with the departure of the CEO
is more likely to cause financial distress or even bankruptcy than it is for
larger and less risky firms. Also consistent with the borrower being more risky,
CMRs tend to be used when the tangibility of borrowers’ assets is lower. For
these borrowers, a CMR may act as a substitute “pledge” for hard assets if
human capital represents a larger portion of firm value relative to the firm’s
hard assets.
To examine human capital explanations more directly, we study the extent to
which CMR inclusion relates to risks arising from the loss of human capital and
the difficulty and/or uncertainty involved in finding an appropriate replacement
for the current CEO. We find that CMRs tend to be included when the borrower’s
CEO is also the company founder (45% of CMR loans compared to 20% of non-
CMR loans), suggesting that lenders may view the cash flow success of the
company as dependent on the founder’s human capital.2Founder CEOs are
likely to have firm-specific skills that make them difficult to replace, which
increases the human capital risk for lenders. Lenders also tend to use CMRs
when the borrower operates in industries in which CEOs tend to be recruited
from within (rather than outside of) the firm. In these industries, managerial
skill tends to be more firm-specific, which is more difficult to transfer to other
firms (Cremers and Grinstein (2014)), and again makes it more difficult to find a
replacement for the CEO. Also consistent with lenders considering replacement
uncertainty, CMRs tend to be present when borrowers have no heir apparent
for the current CEO.
2This evidence provides an interesting contrast regarding the preferred choice of CEO between
lenders and shareholders. Although Kaplan, Sensoy, and Str¨
omberg (2009) show that venture
capitalists tend to favor replacing the founder CEO, we find and study cases in which banks
demand that the founder remain the CEO.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT