Customer Privacy and Competition

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12157
AuthorRune Stenbacka,Oz Shy
Published date01 September 2016
Date01 September 2016
Customer Privacy and Competition
OZSHY
MIT Sloan School of Management
100 Main Street, E62-613, Cambridge, MA 02142
ozshy@ozshy.com
RUNE STENBACKA
Hanken School of Economics
P.O.Box 479 00101 Helsinki Finland
Rune.Stenbacka@hanken.fi
We analyze how different degrees of privacy protection affect industry profits, consumer welfare,
and total welfare in a model with switching costs. Firms earn higher profits under weak privacy
protection compared with strong or no privacy protection. The relationship between the degreeof
privacy protection and equilibrium profits is not monotonic. Consumer surplus and total welfare
increase with the degree of privacy protection unless firms recognize consumer-specific switching
costs. In that case, pricing conditional on switching costs has favorable implications for consumer
surplus and total welfare.
1. Introduction
Technologicalprogress, and, in particular, the Internet, have made it possible for firms to
implement increasingly sophisticated methods of customer recognition that can serve as
a basis for designing discriminatory pricing schemes. In particular, online retail stores,
payment card networks, and search engines collect information that can reveal customer
preferences, willingness to pay, and willingness to try out new brands of a wide variety of
products and services. Overall, the advances in technology have enabled firms to acquire,
store, sell, and share customer-specific information that can be used for implementing
targeted advertising and differential pricing tactics.1
The exploitation of customer-specific information for advertising and pricing pur-
poses raises important privacy concerns.2The Federal Trade Commission has recently
issued a report that establishes best practices for firms to protect consumer privacy
with a recommendation for Congress to consider reforms of the legislation dealing with
Wethank the editor, co-editor,and two anonymous referees for most valuable comments and suggestions. Our
manuscript has benefited from comments by Henrik Horn, Julian Jamison, YossiSpiegel, seminar participants
at The Research Institute of Industrial Economics in Stockholm, NORIO 2012 in Copenhagen, IIOC 2013
in Boston, The Searle Conference on Internet Search and Innovation 2013 at Northwestern University and
CRESSE 2013 on Corfu, as well as from comments by our discussants Eirik Kristiansen, Ludwig von Auer,
Liad Wagman and David Ulph. Financial support fromthe Hanken Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
1. This can be illustrated with a number of examples. An article in the June 30, 2012 issue of The Economist
entitled “How Deep Are YourPockets” describes software designed to detect the willingness of consumers to
pay.A December 7, 2012 Wall Street Journal article entitled “They Know What You’re Shopping For” describes
companies that track and sell information about realidentities of online shoppers. The world’s largest company
of this type, Acxiom, and implied privacy concerns are discussed in a June 16, 2012 New York Times article
entitled “Mapping, and Sharing, the Consumer Genome.”
2. Goldfarb and Tucker (2012) present empirical documentation of how privacy concerns have changed
over time and across age groups.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 3, Autumn 2016, 539–562
540 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
consumer protection, see FTC (2012). Furthermore, Brill (2011) addresses the important
question of how the FTC might balance competition issues with consumer protection
concerns arising in the context of privacy. In particular, should governments regulate
how firms can collect and exchange customer-specific information such as surfing habits
on the Internet, or should firms be trusted to engage in self-regulating as far as privacy is-
sues are concerned? Consumer protection law as well as competition law play important
complementary roles for privacy protection. Hammock and Rubin (2011) emphasize that
high priority should be given to systematic economic analysis of the effects of consumer
privacy protection.
Intuitively, weaker privacy protection may facilitate the design of more aggres-
sive poaching offers. These offers may compensate consumers for their switching costs,
thereby making it possible for these consumers to benefit from intensified competi-
tion. On the other hand, within the framework of an established customer relationship,
an incumbent firm may also be able to exploit weak privacy protection by designing
consumer-specific prices, thereby offsetting the potential benefits from more aggressive
poaching offers. More precisely, with weak privacy protection the firm could target high
prices to those inherited consumers who have strong preference for its brand. It is ex
ante impossible to evaluate the price effects of relaxed privacy protection on industry
profits and consumer surplus without a formal analytical study.
In this study, the degree of privacy protection determines the extent to which
firms can set prices based on consumer-specific information. We evaluate the effects
of mandating firms to adhere to different degrees of privacy protection on industry
profits, consumer surplus, and total welfare. More precisely, we compute, evaluate, and
compare market performance associated with the following three increasing levels of
privacy protection:
rNo privacy (N): Each firm collects information about its customers’ specific preferences
and is mandated to share it with other firms in the industry.Sharing can be facilitated
through, for example, a system of information exchange between the firms.3
rWeak privacy protection (W): Each firm collects information about its own customers’
preferences, but is not allowed to share this information with other firms.
rStrong privacy protection (S): Firms are not allowed to collect information about their
customers’ preferences. However,firms can identify their previous customers and set
different prices to consumers switching from competing brands relative their own
customers.
The present study solves for the price equilibria associated with each of these three
degrees of privacy protection.4In particular, we focus on the following questions: How
do profits depend on the degree of privacy protection? How do different degrees of
privacy protection affect consumer and total welfare? Our benchmark assumption is
that consumers do not view pricing conditional only on their purchase history (what
3. It should be emphasized that this study does not analyze the incentives of firms to engage in information
exchange. The perspective is that of a policy analysis, where we impose differentregimes of privacy protection
and compare the resulting outcomes. Mandated information exchange is a central feature of many industries,
for example the lending industry.Jappelli and Pagano (2002) and Hunt (2005) provide good overviews in this
respect.
4. A conceivable and more strict definition of privacy would be to define complete privacy protection,
which requires firms to set uniform prices. We do not include complete privacy protection in our analysis,
because, as we will make clear later on, a significant number of studies have presented comparisons of
the performance of uniform pricing with the performance under various forms of price discrimination, for
example, behavior-based price discrimination.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT