Credit Rationing, Income Exaggeration, and Adverse Selection in the Mortgage Market

AuthorBRENT W. AMBROSE,JAMES CONKLIN,JIRO YOSHIDA
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12426
Date01 December 2016
Published date01 December 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2016
Credit Rationing, Income Exaggeration, and
Adverse Selection in the Mortgage Market
BRENT W. AMBROSE, JAMES CONKLIN, and JIRO YOSHIDA
ABSTRACT
Weexamine the role of borrower concerns about future credit availability in mitigating
the effects of adverse selection and income misrepresentation in the mortgage market.
We show that the majority of additional risk associated with “low-doc” mortgages
originated prior to the Great Recession was due to adverse selection on the part of
borrowers who could verify income but chose not to. We provide novel evidence that
these borrowers were more likely to inflate or exaggerate their income. Our analysis
suggests that recent regulatory changes that have essentially eliminated the low-doc
loan product would result in credit rationing against self-employed borrowers.
DURING THE GREAT RECESSION OF 2007 to 2008, the United States experienced
a massive increase in residential mortgage defaults and foreclosures not seen
since the Great Depression. For example, the Financial Crisis Inquiry Com-
mission reports that 9.7% of all mortgages were in default by the end of 2009,
compared to approximately 1% at the start of the decade.1While the decline
in house prices between 2007 and 2009 is obviously one of the primary causes
for the significant number of mortgage defaults registered during the crisis,
financial economists have only recently begun to examine the role of mortgage
fraud and adverse selection in exacerbating the consequences of the 2007 to
2009 housing bust. Evidence is mounting that the great mortgage expansion
that accompanied the rise in home prices coincided with increases in mortgage
fraud related to misrepresentations of borrower income (Jiang, Nelson, and
Brent W. Ambrose and Jiro Yoshida are with the Pennsylvania State University Smeal Col-
lege of Business. James Conklin is with the University of Georgia Terry College of Business. We
thank Itzhak Ben-David, Sumit Agarwal, Manuel Adelino, Christopher Palmer, Sam Kruger,Ken
Singleton (Editor), the anonymous Associate Editor and referees, and seminar participants at the
National University of Singapore, University of California–Berkeley,Research Institute of Capital
Formation, Housing Research and Advancement Foundation of Japan, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, University of Cambridge, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Real Estate
Finance Conference, and the 2015 ASSA meeting in Boston for their helpful comments and sug-
gestions. We also thank the Penn State Institute for Real Estate Studies for providing access to
the New Century Mortgage database. We gratefully acknowledge research assistance from Sergio
Garate. The authors have no material financial interests related to this research, as identified in
the journal’s Disclosure Policy; furthermore, no party had the right to review this paper prior to
circulation.
1See U.S. Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (2011, p. 215). Default is defined as “90-days or
more past due or in foreclosure.”
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12426
2637
2638 The Journal of Finance R
Vytlacil (2014), Mian and Sufi (2015)), borrower assets (Garmaise (2015)), in-
flated appraisals (Ben-David (2011), Agarwal, Ambrose, and Yao (2014), Agar-
wal, Ben-David, and Yao (2015), Griffin and Maturana (2015)), and second
liens and owner-occupancy status (Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin (2015)).2As a
result, regulators and policy makers have implemented new rules to combat
perceived abuses in mortgage lending.3The purpose of this paper is to shed
light on how borrower heterogeneity with respect to employment status con-
tributed to income misrepresentation and adverse selection, and how lender
actions and borrower concerns about preserving future access to credit mit-
igated these risks. From a policy perspective, our results echo the concerns
raised by Keys et al. (2009), Rajan, Seru, and Vig (2010), and Piskorski, Seru,
and Vig (2010), among others, concerning the need to carefully weigh the costs
and benefits of new financial regulations.
With respect to income misrepresentation, we present several novel insights.
First, by comparing individual incomes within job titles, we provide new evi-
dence that strongly suggests that income misrepresentation was concentrated
primarily among borrowers who originated low-documentation loans but could
have easily originated full-documentation mortgages instead. Second, unlike
previous studies that show that misrepresentation in mortgage originations
resulted from lender actions at origination,4we find that income falsification
was essentially a borrower-level phenomenon.5Our results therefore suggest
that excesses in the mortgage market in the last decade resulted from both
borrower and lender actions. Third, we provide new evidence on lender actions
in response to potential borrower income falsification. Finally, in additional
analysis examining the role of borrower income falsification in facilitating the
expansion in mortgage credit, we provide new insights into one of the possible
causes of the Great Recession.
The role of borrower income misrepresentation leading up to the financial
crisis is a source of considerable debate. For example, Mian and Sufi (2009)and
Mian and Sufi (2015) argue that borrower income falsification was a leading
culprit in facilitating the expansion of mortgage credit during the 2002 to
2006 housing boom. Supporting this argument, Jiang, Nelson, and Vytlacil
(2014) show that income falsification occurred on low-documentation loans,
2In addition to mispresentation at the loan origination level, Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin (2015)
find that misrepresentation was endemic in the secondary market (between originators and in-
vestors) as well. Furthermore, Agarwal and Evanoff (2013) and Agarwal et al. (2014)provide
evidence of systematic predatory lending practices by loan originators. These practices may have
exacerbated the consequences of mortgage fraud.
3For example, the Consumer Financial Protections Bureau adopted the “Ability to Repay Rule”
that requires lenders to provide greater documentation of borrower income, and the Federal Hous-
ing Finance Agency in conjunction with the New York Attorney General’s office issued the Home
Valuation Code of Conduct (HVCC) that was designed to reduce the incidences of inflated ap-
praisals.
4Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin (2015) is a notable exception. The authors provide evidence that
borrowers misrepresented occupancy status on mortgage applications.
5Note that we are not arguing that the originator was unaware of the misrepresentation, but
rather that borrowers are complicit in falsifying income.
Credit Rationing, Income Exaggeration, and Adverse Selection 2639
resulting in elevated defaults, particularly for loans originated through the
wholesale channel. By focusing on differences in employment status, we show
that the majority of adverse selection and income falsification is confined to a
specific borrower group that was never intended to use the low-documentation
product. Our results therefore suggest that broad policies designed to eliminate
activities associated with excesses in mortgage originations during the housing
boom may have unintended consequences.
Since the potential for mortgage fraud and adverse selection has always been
present, lenders have long relied on underwriting guidelines to limit this risk.
However, Burke, Taylor, and Wagman (2012) illustrate how lender screening
to reject higher risk applicants results in greater adverse selection.6One such
underwriting metric is the debt-to-income (DTI) ratio, which limits the loan
amount based on the borrower’s income. This metric, in combination with the
loan-to-value (LTV) ratio, serves to limit the borrower’s housing consumption.
As a result, borrowers seeking to maximize their housing consumption or in-
vestment have an incentive to exaggerate their income in order to reduce their
DTI ratio and thereby qualify for a higher loan amount.
Recognizing the borrower’s incentive to circumvent these metrics, mortgage
lenders require proof of reported assets and incomes to verify that the borrower
is capable of repaying the debt. Of course, verification of borrower income and
assets comes at a cost. Not only do lenders bear the costs associated with
verification activities, but borrowers also bear costs of collecting and reporting
income and assets to the lender. For some borrowers, these costs are relatively
minor and involve simply submitting the prior two years’ W-2 tax documents
from their employer along with their past two months’ pay stubs. However, for
many other potential borrowers, the costs of verifying income and assets are
not so trivial. For example, self-employed individuals would need to provide
full tax returns for the previous two years. Yet, self-employed individuals often
file for tax return extensions due to the complexity of their tax situation, and as
a result, the returns are not available to the lender. Self-employed individuals
are also required to provide current profit and loss statements along with
bank statements for several months to prove sufficient cash flow to service the
debt. Furthermore, to comply with underwriting DTI guidelines, lenders may
require additional documentation from self-employed borrowers to determine
the nature of deposits and withdrawals and ascertain those expenses that are
personal versus those associated with their business.7
6However,the presence of adverse selection at mortgage origination is not universally accepted.
For example, Agarwal, Chang, and Yavas (2012) rely on differences in loan performance between
prime and subprime markets to claim that adverse selection was less severe in the subprime
market.
7Anecdotal discussions with mortgage brokers and other industry participants provide examples
of the verification costs self-employed borrowers face. For example, lenders may require that self-
employed borrowers provide written explanations for every deposit over the previous year. For a
business with just two transactions per week, that would necessitate over 100 separate written
explanations. Furthermore, many self-employed borrowers face serious confidentiality issues in
revealing client names as the source of deposits.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT