Cream‐Skimming in Financial Markets

Date01 April 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12385
AuthorTANO SANTOS,JOSE A. SCHEINKMAN,PATRICK BOLTON
Published date01 April 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 2 APRIL 2016
Cream-Skimming in Financial Markets
PATRICK BOLTON, TANO SANTOS, and JOSE A. SCHEINKMAN
ABSTRACT
We propose a model in which investors may choose to acquire costly information
that identifies good assets and purchase these assets in opaque (OTC) markets. Un-
informed investors access an asset pool that has been cream-skimmed by informed
investors. When the quality composition of assets for sale is fixed, there is too much
information acquisition and the financial industry extracts excessive rents. In the
presence of moral hazard in origination, the social value of information varies in-
versely with information acquisition. Low quality origination is associated with large
rents in the financial sector. Equilibrium acquisition of information is generically
inefficient.
WHAT DOES THE FINANCIAL industry add to the real economy? What is the optimal
organization of financial markets, and how much talent is required in the
financial industry? We revisit these fundamental questions in light of recent
events and criticisms of the financial industry. The core issue underlying these
questions is whether the financial industry extracts excessively high rents
from the provision of financial services and whether these rents attract too
much talent.1Figure V, Panel B, from Philippon and Reshef (2012, p. 1569)
plots the evolution of U.S. wages (relative to average nonfarm wages) for three
subsegments of the financial services industry: credit, insurance, and “other
finance.” “Credit” refers to banks, S&Ls, and similar institutions; “insurance” to
life and P&C insurers and “other finance” to the financial investment industry
and investment banks. The most remarkable finding is that the bulk of the
Patrick Bolton and Tano Santos are with Columbia University and NBER. Jose A. Scheinkman
is with Columbia University, Princeton University, and NBER. This article was previously circu-
lated under the title “Is the Financial Sector TooBig?” We thank seminar participants at the Bank of
Spain, Cambridge University, CEMFI, EHESS, HEC-Paris, HKUST, INSEAD, London Business
School, London School of Economics, MIT-Sloan, Rochester, Rutgers Business School, Studien-
zentrum Gerzensee, Toulouse School of Economics, University of Virginia-McIntire, Washington
University-Olin Business School, Wharton, and the 6th Banco de Portugal Conference on Mone-
tary Economics for their feedback and suggestions. We also thank Guido Lorenzoni and Marzena
Rostek for detailed comments and Rishab Guha and Linan Qiu for research assistance. This paper
was awarded the 2011 Jaime Fern´
andez Araoz Prize. Bolton acknowledges financial support from
Columbia University and the Fondation Louis Bachelier, Santos acknowledges financial support
from Columbia University, and Scheinkman from Columbia University and Princeton University.
All authors declare no conflict of interest related to this article.
1Goldin and Katz (2008) document that the percentage of male Harvard graduates with posi-
tions in finance 15 years after graduation tripled from the 1970 to the 1990 cohort, largely at the
expense of occupations in law and medicine.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12385
709
710 The Journal of Finance R
growth in remuneration in the financial services industry took place in the
“other finance” sector.
In this paper, we attempt to explain the outsized remuneration in this latter
sector by modeling a financial industry that consists of two sectors: an orga-
nized, regulated, standardized, and transparent market where most retail (i.e.,
plain vanilla) transactions take place, and an informal, opaque sector, where in-
formed professional investors trade and bespoke services are offered to clients.
We refer to the transparent, standardized markets as organized exchanges,
and we refer to the opaque sector as the over-the-counter (OTC) sector even
though in practice not all OTC markets are opaque (e.g., markets for foreign
exchange are quite transparent). A central idea we develop is that, although
OTC markets provide special valuation services to sellers of securities, their
opacity also allows informed dealers to extract informational rents. What is
more, OTC markets cannibalize organized exchanges by “cream-skimming
the juiciest deals away from retail investors.2And, informed investors don’t
just get access to the best assets—they also benefit from the cream-skimming
activities of other informed dealers that help them extract better terms from
the asset sellers. The reason is that cream-skimming worsens the quality of
the pool of assets flowing into the exchange, thereby lowering the price a seller
of a good asset can obtain in the exchange as an outside option. This is how
informed dealers are able to extract outsized terms from the sellers of good
assets. Cream-skimming and outsized remuneration are two sides of the same
coin. Moreover, the outsized informational rents in OTC markets attract tal-
ent to the financial industry, enhancing the cream-skimming externality and
further increasing the information rents extracted by informed dealers. In this
way, growth in OTC markets does not lead to the dissipation of these rents. On
the contrary, dealer remuneration rises as the OTC sector grows, even when
growth is not due to increased demand.
The role of the financial sector in our model is to provide liquidity by allowing
asset originators to sell their assets to investors. A related role is the valuation
of assets for sale when assets vary in quality. This valuation service is offered
by informed dealers in OTC markets. However,although originators are willing
to pay dealers to help them identify valuable assets, in our model there is no
social benefit from these valuation services unless more accurate valuations
also serve the role of providing better origination incentives; otherwise, costly
information acquisition by professional investors only serves the purpose of
cream-skimming the best assets, which is valuable to the trading parties but
has no social value. This result is related to the general observation first made
by Hirshleifer (1971) about the private value of “foreknowledge information,”
2Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) considered a different form of cream-skimming in insurance
markets with adverse selection. In that setting, insurers are uninformed about risk types, but offer
contracts that induce informed agents to self-select into insurance contracts. For an application
of the Rothschild-Stiglitz framework to competition among organized exchanges, see Santos and
Scheinkman (2001).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT