Contracting with Private Knowledge of Production Capacity

Date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12112
AuthorLeon Yang Chu,David E. M. Sappington
Published date01 October 2015
Contracting with Private Knowledge of Production
Capacity
LEON YANG CHU
Marshall School of Business
University of Southern California
3670 TrousdaleParkway, Los Angeles, CA 90089
leonyzhu@usc.edu
DAVID E. M. SAPPINGTON
Department of Economics
Matherly Hall, University of Florida
Gainesville, FL32611-7140
sapping@ufl.edu
We analyze the design of procurement contracts when the supplier is privately informed about
both his innate production capacity (K ) and his innate unit cost of production. We identify
conditions under which the supplier will strategically employ an inefficient production technology
to expand output above K . We also show that when the buyer employs the simple fixed-price
cost-reimbursement (FPCR) contracts in the setting examined by Rogerson (2003), the supplier
has no incentive to exaggerate K . Furthermore, the buyer can secure with FPCR contracts at
least 75% of the surplus she secures with fully optimal contracts.
1. Introduction
In Laffont and Tirole’s (1986) seminal model of procurement and in many extensions of
this model, the supplier is privately informed about his innate unit cost of production
(i.e., his operating cost if he does not deliver any cost-reducing effort). In contrast, these
models typically presume the supplier’s production capacity to be common knowledge.
In particular, it is generally assumed to be common knowledge that the supplier faces
no capacity constraints.
Although this assumption helps to simplify the analysis of theoretical models, ca-
pacity constraints are common in practice. Furthermore, suppliers typically are better in-
formed than buyers about prevailing capacity constraints for several reasons, including
the following two. First, producers often have superior information about the available
supply of critical factors of production. For example, electricity suppliers typically are
privately informed about whether their generating units are fully functional or must
be taken offline for maintenance or repair (Joskow and Kahn, 2002). Second, suppliers
often have privileged knowledge of the contracts they have signed with other buyers,
and consequently have a better understanding of the maximum output they can deliver
to any particular buyer.
We seek to determine whether a buyer’s procurement problem is complicated
by a supplier’s private knowledge of his production capacity. We address this issue
both under unrestricted procurement, where the set of procurementcontracts the buyer
We thank the coeditor and refereesfor very helpful comments and suggestions.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 4, Winter 2015, 752–785
Private Knowledge of Production Capacity 753
can employ is not restricted, as in Laffont and Tirole (1986), and when the buyer em-
ploys fixed-price cost-reimbursement (FPCR) contracts, as analyzed by Rogerson (2003).
FPCR contracts are attractive in part because of their simplicity. FPCR contracts offer the
supplier a choice between: (i) a fixed-price (PR) contract, which sets a specific payment—
independent of the supplier’s realized production costs—at which the buyer will pur-
chase a specified amount of output from the supplier; and (ii) a cost-reimbursement (CR)
contract, under which the buyer simply reimburses the supplier fully for his observed
costs of producing the specified output. As Rogerson (2003) observes, FPCR contracts
are effectively employed, for example, when a defense contractor is afforded the op-
portunity to provide a specified deliverable in return for a fixed payment rather than
operating under the CR policy that the Department of Defense typically employs.1
Rogerson (2003) analyzes a setting in which a buyer procures a single unit of
output from a supplier who is privately informed about his innate cost of produc-
tion. Somewhat remarkably, Rogerson shows that in a fairly broad and arguably plau-
sible set of environments, the buyer can secure with optimally designed FPCR con-
tracts at least 75% of the surplus that she can secure with fully optimal contracts. We
seek to determine whether, in the corresponding setting in which the buyer is not
restricted to procure a single unit of output and in which the supplier is privately
informed about both his innate unit cost of production and his innate capacity, the
buyer can continue to achieve this impressive performance when she employs FPCR
contracts.2
To analyze these issues, we extend Laffont and Tirole (1986)’s classic procurement
model to consider a setting in which the supplier has access to two technologies: a “stan-
dard technology” and a higher cost “alternative technology.” The standard technology,
which has a limited capacity, might be viewed as encompassing the supplier’s nor-
mal operating procedures. The alternative technology might entail the subcontracting
of production to a less efficient supplier, for example, or the unavoidable substitution
of more expensive inputs for the less expensive inputs that the supplier customarily
employs when they are readily available. The alternative technology is presumed to be
inefficient in the sense that the unit cost of production using this technology (βa) exceeds
the buyer’s unit valuation of output (v).
The supplier produces output at constant unit cost under both technologies. The
supplier is privately informed about: (i) the capacity (K) of the standard technology;
(ii) the innate unit cost of production (β) for output below capacity using the standard
technology; (iii) the effort he devotes to reducing his unit cost of production under
the standard technology; and (iv) the amount of output he produces using each tech-
nology. We examine whether, in addition to his normal incentive to exaggerate β,the
supplier may find it profitable to misrepresent K. The supplier can understate Kwith
1. Rogerson (2003) also notes that a regulator can be viewed as employing FPCR contracts when she
offers the regulated firm a choice between rate of return regulation and price cap regulation. Sappington
(2002) describes a related policy that the U.S. Federal Communications Commission has implemented. The
policy affords suppliers of telecommunications services a choice between prices that are not explicitly linked
to realized production costs and prices that can vary as realized earnings increase above or decline below
specified thresholds.
2. Rogerson (2003) derives his key finding in a setting where the supplier’s innate cost has a uniform
distribution, the supplier’s personal cost of delivering cost-reducing effort eis a quadratic function of e,and
the buyer effectively values only one unit of the product that she procures.We focus on corresponding settings
in which the buyer derives value v>0 from each unit of output that she procures. Alternative settings are
discussed in the concluding section.
754 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
impunity.He can also exaggerate Kby employing the alternative production technology
to generate output in excess of K.3
We find that the supplier generally has no incentive to understate K.4However,
under unrestricted procurement, the supplier may sometimes find it profitable to exag-
gerate Kby employing the high-cost technology to deliver output in excess of K.Thisis
the case because the larger is the supplier’s output, the more rapidly his total production
cost declines as his increased effort reduces his unit cost of production. Consequently,
the more output the buyer procures, the more cost-reducing effort she typically induces
the supplier to deliver.The supplier secures increased rent from the associated expanded
opportunity to substitute a low innate cost (β) for cost-reducing effort.
In contrast, the supplier does not find it optimal to employ the alternative tech-
nology to increase output above his innate capacity when the buyer employs FPCR
contracts. This conclusion reflects, in part, the fact that under the optimal set of FPCR
contracts, the fixed payment increases with delivered output at a rate that is less than v,
the buyer’s marginal valuation of output. Consequently,because the supplier ’s marginal
cost of production using the alternative production technology (βa) exceeds v,thein-
cremental revenue the supplier can secure by employing the alternative technology to
expand output is less than the corresponding incremental cost.
In addition to mitigating the supplier’s incentive to exaggerate his production
capacity, optimally designed FPCR contracts continue to secure for the buyer at least
75% of the surplus that she can secure with fully optimal contracts. Therefore, Rogerson’s
important observation about the performance of FPCR contracts extends to settings in
which the supplier is privately informed about both βand Kand in which the buyer
procures multiple units of the supplier’s product.5
Our derivation and presentation of these findings proceeds as follows. Section 2
describes our model. Section 3 provides a formal statement of the buyer’s problem under
unrestricted procurement. Section 4 identifies the outcomes that arise in two benchmark
settings: one in which the buyer is fully informed about both the supplier’s innate
production capacity (K) and his innate unit cost (β) and one in which the buyer is fully
informed only about K. Section 5 specifies conditions under which the buyer’s limited
knowledge of Kis constraining under unrestricted procurement. Section 6 demonstrates
that the supplier is not constrained by her limited knowledge of Kwhen she employs
FPCR contracts. Section 6 also proves that when she employs FPCR contracts in this
setting, the buyer can always secure at least 75% of the surplus that she can secure
under unrestricted procurement. Section 7 concludes and suggests directions for future
research. The Appendix presents the proofs of all formal conclusions that do not appear
in the text.
3. Thus, as in Lacker and Weinberg(1989) and Kartik (2009), the supplier can misrepresent the prevailing
environment by undertaking personally costly “falsification” activities.
4. Incentives to understate capacity can arise in other settings where, for example, the suppliers of a
commodity (e.g., electricity) are paid a unit price that equates the realizeddemand and supply of a commodity.
See Borenstein et al. (2002), Joskow and Kahn (2002), and Tellidouand Bakirtzis (2007).
5. In contrast to other analyses of multidimensional adverse selection problems (e.g., McAfee and McMil-
lan, 1988; Rochet and Chon´
e, 1998; Armstrong and Rochet, 1999), we do not characterize the optimal contract
for the buyer under unrestricted procurement.We explain in Section 6 why this characterization is not required
to demonstrate our primary conclusion, namely, that the buyer can secure with FPCR contracts at least 75%
of the surplus that she can secure under unrestricted contracting.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT