Consumption Volatility Risk

AuthorLARS‐ALEXANDER KUEHN,OLIVER BOGUTH
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12058
Date01 December 2013
Published date01 December 2013
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVIII, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2013
Consumption Volatility Risk
OLIVER BOGUTH and LARS-ALEXANDER KUEHN
ABSTRACT
We show that time variation in macroeconomic uncertainty affects asset prices. Con-
sumption volatility is a negatively priced source of risk for a wide variety of test portfo-
lios. At the firm level, exposure to consumption volatility risk predicts future returns,
generating a spread across quintile portfolios in excess of 7% annually.This premium
is explained by cross-sectional differences in the sensitivity of dividend volatility to
consumption volatility. Stocks with volatile cash flows in uncertain aggregate times
require higher expected returns.
IT HAS LONG BEEN recognized that the volatility of macroeconomic quantities,
such as consumption and output, varies over time.1Surprisingly, the impact of
consumption growth volatility on asset prices has received little attention in
empirical tests of consumption-based pricing models2—most papers use only
the first moment of consumption growth (e.g., Lettau and Ludvigson (2001),
Parker and Julliard (2005), and Yogo (2006)). The contribution of this paper
is to show that exposure to time-varying consumption volatility leads to a
risk premium that can be explained by cross-sectional differences in cash flow
loadings. Stocks with volatile dividends in uncertain aggregate times require
higher expected returns.
Oliver Boguth is with the W. P. Carey School of Business at Arizona State University. Lars-
Alexander Kuehn is with the Tepper School of Business at Carnegie Mellon University. We thank
Murray Carlson; Alexander David; Wayne Ferson; Adlai Fisher; Lorenzo Garlappi; Cam Harvey;
Burton Hollifield; Lars Lochstoer; Monika Piazzesi; Lukas Schmid; Amir Yaron; Motohiro Yogo;
Lu Zhang; seminar participants at Berkeley, Carnegie Mellon University, University of British
Columbia, and Wharton; as well as conference participants at the 2009 Annual Meetings of the
Western Finance Association, European Finance Association, and Northern Finance Association,
the 2009 North American Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society, the 2009 Centre for
Economic Policy Research Gerzensee Summer Symposium on Financial Markets, and the 2010
Annual Meeting of the American Economics Association for valuable comments. We also thank
Kenneth French for providing data on his website.
1See, among others, Cecchetti and Mark (1990), Kandel and Stambaugh (1990), and Kim and
Nelson (1999).
2Notable exceptions are Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron (2007), who estimate the conditional first
and second moments of consumption growth as affine functions of financial data, and Tedongap
(2007), who uses a GARCH process for consumption volatility. Other contributions testing the
consumption-based capital asset pricing model (Consumption-CAPM) using realized consumption
growth include Campbell (1996), Campbell and Vuolteenaho(2004), Bansal, Dittmar, and Lundblad
(2005), Lustig and Nieuwerburgh (2005), and Jagannathan and Wang (2007).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12058
2589
2590 The Journal of Finance R
Toguide our empirical exercise, we follow the work of Kandel and Stambaugh
(1991), Bansal and Yaron (2004), and Lettau, Ludvigson, and Wachter (2008).
The representative agent has recursive Epstein and Zin (1989) preferences and
the conditional first and second moments of consumption growth follow Markov
chains with unobservable states. These preferences imply that the agent’s esti-
mates of the conditional first and second moments of consumption growth are
priced. More specifically,when the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS)
is greater than the inverse of the coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA), the
agent prefers that intertemporal risk due to unobservable Markov states be
resolved sooner rather than later. As a result, the agent demands a negative
price of risk for shocks to the conditional volatility of consumption growth, im-
plying that high expected returns are associated with both low return exposure
and high cash flow volatility exposure to consumption volatility.
Following Hamilton (1989), we estimate a Markov chain for the first and sec-
ond moments of consumption growth. While we retain the common assumption
that the representative agent has preferences over total consumption, defined
as the sum of nondurable and service consumption expenditures, we improve
state identification by using both components of consumption separately in the
estimation. In particular, we assume that both service consumption growth as
well as changes in the share of service to total consumption follow Markov
chains. Total consumption growth is obtained by aggregating the two compo-
nents, and therefore follows the same process. The precision of the resulting
estimates is increased as indicated by reduced standard errors.
Our first empirical evidence on the pricing of consumption volatility is based
on market prices of risk obtained from regressions of average excess returns on
estimated loadings on log consumption growth, as well as changes in the per-
ceived mean and volatility of consumption growth using portfolios. To alleviate
the critique of Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010), we use not only the 25
Fama–French portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market but also portfolios
sorted on industry and book-to-market as well as net share issuance (NSI) and
size. Surprisingly, our empirical analysis shows no evidence that beliefs about
the mean consumption growth are priced. Consumption growth volatility, how-
ever, is robustly priced in the cross-section. Importantly, the price of volatility
risk is negative, consistent with preference for early resolution of uncertainty.
This is a crucial assumption in the long-run risk framework of Bansal and
Yaron (2004) and our findings strongly support it.
We also study the relation between risk loadings and future returns at the
firm level as emphasized by Ang, Liu, and Schwarz (2010). To obtain time-
varying risk loadings, we run rolling quarterly time-series regressions of in-
dividual stock returns on consumption growth as well as innovations in be-
liefs for the mean and volatility of consumption growth. Evidence from both
Fama–MacBeth regressions and portfolio sorts suggests that loadings on ex-
pected consumption growth do not help to explain future returns. Loadings on
consumption growth volatility,however, significantly negatively forecast cross-
sectional differences in returns. This firm level evidence thus corroborates the
negative price of consumption volatility risk (CVR) estimated from portfolios.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT