Consumer Standards as a Strategic Device to Mitigate Ratchet Effects in Dynamic Regulation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12104
AuthorRaffaele Fiocco,Roland Strausz
Date01 September 2015
Published date01 September 2015
Consumer Standards as a Strategic Device to
Mitigate Ratchet Effects in Dynamic Regulation
RAFFAELE FIOCCO
Department of Economics
University of Mannheim
L7, 3-5, D-68131 Mannheim Germany
raffaele.fiocco@uni-mannheim.de
ROLAND STRAUSZ
Institute for Economic Theory I
Humboldt-Universit¨
at zu Berlin
Spandauer Str. 1 D-10178 Berlin Germany
strauszr@wiwi.hu-berlin.de
Strategic delegation to an independent regulator with a pure consumer standard improves dy-
namic regulation by mitigating ratchet effects associated with short-term contracting. A pure
consumer standard alleviates the regulator’s myopic temptation to raise output after learning
the firm is inefficient. Anticipating this tougher regulatory behavior, efficient firms find it less
attractive to exaggerate costs. This reduces the need for long-term rents and mitigates ratchet ef-
fects. A welfare standard biased toward consumers entails, however, allocative costs arising from
partial separation of the firms’ cost types. A trade-off results, which favors strategic delegation
when efficient firms are relatively likely.
1. INTRODUCTION
Ratchet effects associated with short-term contracting due to limited regulatory commit-
ment represent one of the major practical problems in dynamic regulation.1Intuitively,
the ratchet problem follows from the regulator’s inability to commit not to use against the
firm in the future any cost information inferred from the firm’s actions in earlier periods.
In the absence of commitment, the regulator succumbs to the temptation to expropriate
the firm’s rents after learning such new information. Anticipating that it jeopardizes
future rents, the firm is less inclined to disclose its information. This reluctance to reveal
information reduces social welfare.
This paper investigates the scope for strategic delegation to an independent reg-
ulatory agency in a dynamic regulatory framework with ratchet effects. We show that
establishing a regulator with a mandate that assigns a lower weight on firm profits
than the legislators’ preferences acts as a strategic device that mitigates ratchet effects.
This mandate places more emphasis on rent extraction and induces the regulator to be
tougher toward the firm. The optimal regulatory objective exhibits a zero weight on
We thank the coeditor and two anonymous referees for their constructive comments and suggestions. We
are grateful to Helmut Bester and Mikhail Drugov for helpful discussions and remarks. We also thank the
participants at CRESSE Conference in Crete 2012 and CCRP Workshopin Vienna 2012. Financial support by
the DFG (German Science Foundation) under SFB649 is gratefully acknowledged.
1. For a deeper discussion on diverse regulatory commitment problems, we refer to Levy and Spiller
(1996) and Newbery (1999).
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 3, Fall 2015, 550–569
Consumer Standards as a Strategic Device 551
profits, and therefore the regulator is assigned a pure consumer standard.Hence, a pure
consumer standard improves the dynamic efficiency of short-term regulatory contracts.
In contrast, we do not find any beneficial strategic delegation effect of a more lenient
regulator.
Prima facie, the result that a tougher regulator mitigates ratchet effects seems coun-
terintuitive. Since the ratchet problem implies that the regulator is unable to hand out
long-term rents, standard intuition would suggest that, if strategic delegation is to mit-
igate ratchet effects, then it can do so only via a regulator who is less eager to extract
rents. This reasoning would lead to the opposite conclusion that the regulator should be
more lenient with the firm.
Our analysis shows that this intuition is misleading, because it neglects a crucial
driver of the ratchet problem: the regulator’s temptation to raise the firm’s output after
learning it is inefficient. Toillustrate our results, we consider a two-period version of the
seminal Baron and Myerson (1982) monopoly regulation model, where a firm has private
information about its time invariant marginal costs. A fundamental insight of the Baron
and Myerson model is that the firm’s private information leads the regulator to trade off
allocative efficiency against rent extraction. The reason why tougher regulation helps to
mitigate ratchet effects is directly related to this fundamental trade-off. A regulator with
full commitment powers can optimally refrain from using the pertinent information and
commit to an ex post inefficiently low output of the inefficient firm in order to reduce
the socially costly informational rents to the efficient firm. However, a regulator who
can only use short-term contracts succumbs to the temptation to raise the output of the
inefficient firm after learning its private information. This myopic regulatory behavior
triggers the ratchet problem, because the efficient firm anticipates a higher output for
the inefficient firm, and therefore it expects to receive higher rents in the second period
if it claims to be inefficient in the first period. A regulatory objective with a lower profit
weight reduces the regulator’s temptation to raise the inefficient firm’s output, because
the lower profit weight induces the regulator to place more emphasis on rent extraction
via a downward output distortion. This limits the need for long-term rents to the efficient
firm and mitigates ratchet effects. Hence, rather than restoring the regulator’s ability to
hand out long-term rents, it is preferable to mitigate the ratchet problem by assigning
the regulator a pure consumer standard that reduces the need for long-term rents. This
explains our result that tougher regulators improve the dynamics of regulation in the
presence of ratchet effects.
Strategic delegation with a pure consumer standard entails, however, allocative
costs because it induces partial separation contracts that create a partial “mismatch”
between the firm’s cost types and contracts. Hence, a trade-off results, which shifts in
favor of strategic delegation with the likelihood of the efficient firm. Strategic delegation
is therefore optimal when the efficient firm is relatively likely. Otherwise, a regulator
with an unbiased welfare perspective is preferable.
Our results are consistent with the mandate of modern independent regulatory
agencies that focus their attention on consumers, while downplaying the role of profits.
For example, Section 2A of the UK WaterIndustry Act 1991 states that the Water Services
Regulation Authority “shall exercise and perform the powers [...] to further the consumer
objective,” while mentioning with regard to firm profits that the Authority’s duty is “to
secure that companies [...] are able [...] to finance the proper carrying out of those
functions.” Consequently, profits are viewed only as an indirect mean for regulators to
achieve their primary goal of serving consumers. Similarly, Ofgem, the UK Office of
the Gas and Electricity Markets, states that “protecting consumers is our first priority,”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT