Consumer Ruthlessness and Mortgage Default during the 2007 to 2009 Housing Bust

Date01 December 2017
AuthorHUI SHAN,NEIL BHUTTA,JANE DOKKO
Published date01 December 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12523
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2017
Consumer Ruthlessness and Mortgage Default
during the 2007 to 2009 Housing Bust
NEIL BHUTTA, JANE DOKKO, and HUI SHAN
ABSTRACT
From 2007 to 2009 U.S. house prices plunged and mortgage defaults surged. While os-
tensibly consistent with widespread “ruthless default,” analysis of detailed mortgage
and house price data indicates that borrowers do not walk away until they are deeply
underwater—far deeper than traditional models predict. The evidence suggests that
lender recourse is not the major driver of this result. We argue that emotional and
behavioral factors play an important role in decisions to continue paying. Borrower
reluctance to walk away implies that the moral hazard cost of default as a form of
social insurance may be lower than suspected.
FROM 2007 TO 2009 HOUSE PRICES in the United States plunged, especially in
many areas of Arizona, California, Florida, and Nevada (Figure 1). At roughly
the same time, mortgage defaults surged, consistent with the predictions of
option-theoretic models of mortgage pricing where borrowers “ruthlessly” de-
fault to maximize their wealth (Foster and Van Order (1984,1985)). Numerous
media anecdotes suggest that ruthless defaults were widespread, and the pre-
sumed wave of such defaults has led economists and policy makers to propose
ways to address ruthless or strategic defaulters. In this paper, we assess how
closely borrower behavior conforms to neoclassical models of default using rich
microdata where we know the precise timing of defaults and the evolution of
house prices at the ZIP code level.
We find that home equity has to turn deeply negative before most homeown-
ers will exercise their default “option”—much more so than the neoclassical
models predict. In particular, we estimate that the median borrower in our
Neil Bhutta is from the Federal Reserve Board and Hui Shan is from Goldman, Sachs &
Co. The bulk of the work for this paper was conducted when Dokko was at the Federal Reserve
Board and the Brookings Institution. Cheryl Cooper provided excellent research assistance. We
thank Sarah Davies of VantageScore Solutions for sharing estimates of how mortgage defaults
impact credit scores. We also thank Brian Bucks, Glenn Canner,Ronel Elul, Kris Gerardi, Andrew
Haughwout, Jerry Hausman, Benjamin Keys, Andreas Lehnert, Michael Palumbo, Karen Pence,
Monika Piazzesi, Stuart Rosenthal, Shane Sherlund, Bill Wheaton, and Paul Willen for helpful
comments and suggestions. The findings and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors
and do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve System or the U.S. Government. The authors
have no financial conflicts of interest to disclose in conducting this research. An early version of
this paper was voluntarily submitted to the Federal Reserve’s Finance and Economic Discussion
working paper series, and was reviewed by other Federal Reserve Board staff prior to release in
the series.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12523
2433
2434 The Journal of Finance R
Figure 1. Home prices in selected metropolitan areas, January 1987 to August 2010.
This figure shows home price indices from Case-Shiller for four major metropolitan areas in the
four states that we study. The price indexes are adjusted for overall inflation using the all-urban
Consumer Price Index (CPI ) from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and are set to 100 in January
1987.
sample does not exercise the default option until his housing equity drops to
74% (i.e., the cumulative loan-to-home-value (CLTV) ratio is 174%, which
equates to a loan balance—including first and second mortgages—of about
$348,000 on a $200,000 house). In contrast, the traditional frictionless option-
theoretic model predicts that default is certain once equity reaches about 20%
(Kau, Keenan, and Kim (1994)).
Although many papers demonstrate that negative equity makes default more
likely (e.g., Deng, Quigley, and van Order (2000), Bajari, Chu, and Park (2008),
Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2008)), understanding whether the ruthless model
effectively characterizes consumer behavior requires further analysis. We de-
velop a novel strategy to estimate the distribution of threshold equity values
implied by the empirical relationship between equity and default. In a recent
survey that Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2013) draw on, homeowners were
asked a series of questions to gauge how deeply underwater they would have
to be to walk away from their mortgage. For example, the survey asks, “If the
value of your mortgage exceeded the value of your house by $50,000, would you
walk away from your house even if you could afford to pay your monthly mort-
gage?” This type of question provides the intuition for our analysis, but we infer
Consumer Ruthlessness and Mortgage Default 2435
the threshold level of negative equity needed to induce default by examining
actual payment decisions of people who bought their homes at the peak of the
housing market in 2006 and started falling “underwater” soon thereafter. Al-
though many borrowers say they would not default in certain situations, they
may act differently.
The housing crisis has reignited a longstanding debate about whether mort-
gage borrowers ruthlessly exercise the default or put option. On the one hand,
Cunningham and Hendershott (1984) propose that transaction and “psychic”
costs could be substantial, and Foster and van Order (1985) provide initial em-
pirical evidence of an underexercise of default by underwater borrowers.1On
the other hand, Kau, Keenan, and Kim (1994) show that rational borrowers
may not default until equity falls well below zero even in the absence of trans-
action costs, and argue that the available evidence supports the frictionless
model.
Research on this topic can inform not just mortgage pricing questions, but
also policy issues concerning the penalties for default, regulatory considera-
tions, such as caps on loan-to-value ratios, and loss forecasting in the event
that house prices severely decline again (e.g., stress tests). Moreover, consider-
able improvements in data on loan performance and house prices, as well as in
econometric methods, can help answer these questions more precisely.
We focus primarily on the monthly payment status of over 125,000 nonprime
home purchase loans originated in 2006 in Arizona, California, Florida, and
Nevada, as well as a monthly measure of home equity computed from highly
disaggregated ZIP code level house price indexes (HPI). All of the borrowers in
this sample put no money down (a combined loan-to-value of 100) and many
purchased homes in ZIP codes where house prices declined by over 50% be-
tween 2006 and 2009. These loans were packaged into private-label mortgage
securities and defaulted at an extremely high rate, and have been a central
focus of research on the triggers of the financial crisis. If borrowers typically
refrain from walking away until their equity falls deeply and they are severely
underwater, this would imply that borrower behavior largely deviates from
that predicted by traditional option-theoretic models.
Because our main sample is not representative of the population of home
buyers, we also examine a broader set of loans from an alternative data set
that includes loans sold to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, loans held in banks’
portfolios, and loans with modest down payments. If borrowers in this sample
also tend not to default until falling deeply underwater, this would further
support the view that mortgage borrowers’ behavior generally deviates from
the traditional model.
Our methodology addresses a key empirical challenge, namely, that default
can occur because of liquidity shocks that necessitate default and lead to in-
correct inferences about walk-away thresholds. If, for example, we observe an
individual defaulting when his CLTV ratio hits 125% (or, equivalently, equity
1Subsequent work by Quigley and van Order (1995) also points to an underexercise of the
default option.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT