Conflict Management in Illicit Drug Cryptomarkets

AuthorCarlo Morselli,Masarah Paquet-Clouston,David Décary-Hétu,Judith Aldridge
DOI10.1177/1057567717709498
Published date01 December 2017
Date01 December 2017
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Conflict Management in Illicit
Drug Cryptomarkets
Carlo Morselli
1
, David De
´cary-He
´tu
1
,
Masarah Paquet-Clouston
1
, and Judith Aldridge
2
Abstract
Illegal drug markets have been described as “stateless” systems. Drug dealers, moreover, are
commonly considered to have a predilection toward the use of violence to resolve disputes arising
from dealing activities. While some studies have undermined this popular perception, new trends
surrounding the distribution of illegal drugs via online channels (drug cryptomarkets) have shifted
the transactional setting from the physical to virtual realm, thus decreasing the likelihood of violent
resolution outcomes even further. This article examines conflict management strategies within
cryptomarkets by coding discussion forums between vendors and buyers. Violence, as expected, is
absent. Strategies more likely reflect alternatives that have been recognized in conflict management
research within and beyond illegal mark et settings: tolerance, avoidance, os tracism, third-party
intervention, negotiation, and threats. The overall setting from which such resolutions emerge is
clearly not subject to formal regulations, but our analyses illustrate the multitude of informal social
control mechanisms that are consistently at play and which underlie the self-regulatory and
communal processes that are firmly in place.
Keywords
conflict management, violence, illegal drugs, cryptomarkets, self-regulation
Illegal drug markets, in keeping with illegal markets more generally, have been described as
“stateless” settings (Wilkins, 2001), leaving participan ts to resolve their problems and disputes
without the benefit of formal mediating agents and guidelines (Cooney, 1998; Jacques, 2010;
Reuter, 1983). Without legally binding contractual arrangements afforded by the state, illegal drug
markets have been argued to go hand-in-hand with violence. In his tripartite framework, Goldstein
(1985, 1997) remains explicit in regard to this association: “violence is intrinsic to involvement with
any illicit substance” (Goldstein, 1985, p. 497). This drug–violence nexus is designed around
psychopharmacological (violence due to the effects of a drug), economic compulsi ve (violence
1
Centre international de criminologie compare
´e / School of Criminology, Universite
´de Montre
´al, Montre
´al, Canada
2
University of Manchester, Manchester, UK
Corresponding Author:
Carlo Morselli, Universite
´de Montre
´al, C.P. 6128, succursale Centre-ville, Montre
´al, Que
´bec, Canada H3C 3J7.
Email: carlo.morselli@umontreal.ca
International CriminalJustice Review
2017, Vol. 27(4) 237-254
ª2017 Georgia State University
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1057567717709498
journals.sagepub.com/home/icj
enacted when stealing to buy drugs), and systemic (violence because of extralegal transactional
issues) features. While support for the nexus has been found when focusing on the experiences of
consumers (see Copes, Hochstetler, & Sandberg, 2015), the prevalence and consistency of violence
has been less clear-cut when examining the supply side of illegal drug trafficking settings.
Some researchers construe violence as a social phenomenon, even before considering the selling
of drugs specifically. Violence, in this sense, pervades all spheres of a drug dealer’s life. Sommers
and Baskin (1997) consider that the violence of drug sellers stems not from the distribution of drugs,
but rather from the drug underworld that provides a context that favors the use of violence within a
larger social environment. Pearson and Hobbs (2001, p. 41) concur: “many of those featuring
prominently in middle market drug dealing networks bring with them prior reputations for violent
action,” with some drug trade participants predisposed to violence even before becoming involved in
drug selling. Support for this perspective is demonstrated by the finding that certain drug markets,
such as those dealing in cocaine or crack, are more violent than other illegal drug markets (Fagan &
Chin, 1990; Johnson, Golub, & Fagan, 1995), suggesting that it is not marketplace illegality per se
that deterministically creates violence. Moreover, we find considerable variation in violence con-
nected to drug trafficking across countries, with recent increases (e.g., Mexico) and decreases (e.g.,
Colombia) in violence not simply linked to the existence and persistence of trafficking in these
locations (Duran-Martinez, 2015).
For others, the place of violence in illegal drug settings has been largely overstated. Reuter (2009)
has stressed that illegal drug markets are relatively peaceful. Violence has been found to be a last
resort, with general consensus identifying the importance of the multiple alternatives to violence
employed by drug market actors (Meeson & Morselli, 2012). Contrary to the leading assumption
underlying Goldstein’s framework, Jacques and Wright (2008, pp. 222–223) argue that violence “is
not an invariant or inevitable feature of drug markets; many such markets experience little or no
serious violence, and even the most violent drug markets are peaceful most of the time.” Dickinson
(2017) also provides similar evidence on the importance of avoiding violence in drug dealing
settings, with firsthand examples of dealers practicing prevention by offering free drugs to clients
so as to avoid snitching and eventual enforcement (see also Dickinson & Wright, 2015). Dickinson’s
dealers were more likely to threaten clients with avoidance than violence. Such assertions are also
supported by Coomber (2006) who also describes drug dealing experiences that, in general, indicate
that the claim that violence is systematic or systemic in illegal drug markets is largely overstated.
Ethnographic research also supports such an appraisal. Taylor’s (2007) study of drug dealing
disputes illustrates that outcomes are generally influenced by the seriousness of the dispute and the
relational features uniting participants in conflict. Most drug dealing conflicts were found to present
little harm and ill intent. For those that were more serious, the likelihood of violence was largely
dependent on a preceding enemy link between conflicting parties; friends and long-standing busi-
ness partners were more likely to find nonviolent resolutions. However, and as Jacques’s (2008)
critique of Taylor’s book also makes apparent, there is much more to this resolution setting than a
clear-cut dichotomy between violence and nonviolence. Jacques’s point touches on a crucial fallacy
emerging from many past drug market settings: The focus on violence in illegal drug markets has
generally been approached from a simplistic outlook, lacking the comparison with nonviolence or
the even more nuanced assessment that would integrate specific forms of nonviolent outcomes.
Much of past research on violence in illegal drug markets (and illegal markets in general) has been
tainted by a self-fulfilling prophecy that has us searching for violence and only violence. This fallacy
suggests that, if we look for violence in illegal drug settings, we will find it, but this does not allow us
to generalize such observations to a market as a whole. Essentially, violence is but one form of
conflict management and scenes of violence must therefore be situated within a wider repertoire of
conflict management and resolution alternatives. The importance of such alternatives is best
expressed by one of the drug dealers who shared his experience and despair with having to resolve
238 International Criminal Justice Review 27(4)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT